.


SCI LIBRARY

The Thirty Years of Henry George

Charles B. Fillebrown



[Reprinted from the book, Natural Taxation, published 1917.
Part I / The Authorities / Chapter 12]


In 1879 Henry George in California wrote Progress and Poverty, a book which met with a wide sale and general review, especially in the Australasian and Canadian dominions, as well as in Scotland in England, with early translation into German. The principles of the single tax had been clearly stated as early as the latter part of 18th-century, but Mr. George was the man of all men up to his time to expound, exploit, and advertise the doctrine in full and logical sequence. Practical agitation of this reform dates from the appearance of Progress and Poverty.

In 1882 Mr. George stumped Ireland, and again in 1884 made a three months' tour throughout Great Britain, speaking in the principle cities to large audiences, and making a strong impression. In 1890 there followed a nine months' trip to Australia and around the world.

Great reforms can usually be traced to their ultimate sources in the thought and utterances of great men, and it appears that from the seeds sewn during these tours their sprang the English movement for land taxation. It is particularly interesting to note that it was less than two years after Henry George's visit that New Zealand began to enact tax laws looking to the concentration of local taxes upon the land. In England, Germany, Australasia and, and Canada, the last 15 or 20 years have seen important changes in the methods of taxation, which single taxers may justly consider advances in their direction.


I. BRITISH COLUMBIA[1]


Of the nine Canadian provinces three have taken importance steps toward the single tax. In British Columbia provincial revenue is still derived from poll, property, and income taxes; but since 1891 municipalities have been permitted to exempt improvements from taxation in part or in whole. Since 1892, in fact, municipalities have not been permitted to assess improvements at more than 50 per cent of their actual value. Under the authority thus granted, all the important urban and many world municipalities now exempt improvements, thus raising practically all local revenue from land. The following cases furnish the best examples of this tendency:

Burnaby. -- A municipality bordering on Vancouver, has from its incorporation in 1892 totally exempted improvements from taxation. The rate on a wild lands is practically double that upon improved liens.

New Westminster. -- Adjoining Burnaby, oldest municipality in the province, charted in 1860; improvements exempted from taxation in 1911 by a vote of 248, against 98. Ratification by a vote of the Council unanimous. Population over 20,000; value of land, $16,600,000.

North Vancouver. -- Incorporated in 1906, when it was set off from the district of North Vancouver, which during its existence of over twenty years has never taxed improvements. The city of North Vancouver in 1911 assessed land at $9,400,000 and improvements at $1,420,000, or nearly double the valuation of the previous year.

Point Gray. -- A residential suburb of Vancouver, seat of the University of British Columbia, population in 1911, 30,000; incorporated as a municipality in 1908; improvements exempted from taxation. Wild lands taxed at a rate nearly double that upon improved liens.

South Vancouver. -- Population 30,000; incorporated as a municipality in 1892; 50 per cent of improvements then exempted from taxation. Improvements totally exempt since 1903.

Vancouver. -- Population in 1914 about 110,000; value of land $150,000,000; improvements $76,000,000. Terminus of the Canadian Pacific Railroad; has one of the finest natural harbors and the world, and is the chief shipping port for Japan, China, Australia, etc. Largest city of the province. In 1896 50 per cent of the value of improvements was exempted from taxation. Ten years later in 1906 the exemption was increased to 75 per cent. In 1910 the exemption was made complete. L. D. Taylor, then Mayor of Vancouver, says of it:

From the beginning the cities of the Canadian West have taken the initiative in promoting the single-tax policy by putting it into actual operation, while other municipal governments have not reached beyond the theoretical. Vancouver's policy of valuing land at full capital value and improvements at only 50 per cent, thereby taxing building only half as much as sites, was adopted long before the single tax leaders had begun their campaign of education that today reaches around world. And so satisfactory was this first experiment that when the further reduction of 25 per cent was made, so as to tax the capital value of improvements only one-quarter as much as that of sites, the opposition was so small as to be scarcely worth taking into account. The last step taken -- the adoption of the single tax system in its entirety -- has placed Vancouver in the unique position of being the only city of metropolitan size of the continent to elect a municipal government on a single tax platform.


Victoria. -- The capital of the province; population over 30,000 in 1911. After exempting 25 per cent of the value of improvements from 1894 to 1896, and 50 per cent from 1896 to 1911, Victoria made the exemption complete in 1911. The assessed value of land in 1913 was $89 million.


II. ALBERTA[2]


In this province the term "town" refers only to such places as are incorporated as towns under a town act. It does not include villages or rural municipalities. Rural municipalities were first organized in 1912, and were required without exception to levy their taxes on land values only. Fifty-two were established during the first year. Ninety-seven of the ninety-eight villages and forty-five of the forty-seven towns existing in 1914 were required to tax land values only. This being a very new country, the number of rural municipalities, villages, and towns is rapidly increasing.

Until 1913 to provincial taxes in Alberta were confined practically to taxes on corporations, railways, and inheritances. In that year, however, the province passed what is apparently the first unearned increment tax law to be placed upon an American statute book. By this law the provincial treasury at transfer takes one 20th of all increases in urban land values. In 1914 the province decided to meet its war quota by levying attacks on wild lands at the rate of 10 mills on the dollar. In 1950 in the province received about $1,500,000 from the proceeds of this tax.

Several cities and many villages, under authority granted them, have for years exempted improvements or assessed them at part of their value only. In 1912 the province enacted three laws, practically without opposition, requiring the towns, with two exceptions, all rural municipalities, and all villages, to raise their total revenues exclusively from taxes assessed upon land according to its actual cash value.

The six cities in the province have special charters which grant them wide discretion taxation. Edmonton and Medicine Hat tax land only. The other four are gradually changing their methods with a view to abolishing taxes on improvements within a few years. The city of Red Deer has a small-business tax only in addition to the tax on land.

Edmonton, which in 1914 at a population of about 75,000, has exempted improvements since 1904. It also controls all public utilities, owning and operating water works, electrical lighting and power plant, street railways, and a telephone system.


III. SASKATCHEWAN


In all rural municipalities land values alone are taxed. In 1914 these municipalities began to levy an additional taxed about 6 1/4 cents per acre on uncultivated lands, with the object of discouraging speculation.

Cities, towns, and villages formerly assessed improvements at 60 per cent of their value. In 1908, however, villages were permitted to confine taxation to lands, excluding improvements, and no less than thirty have already availed themselves of this opportunity. In 1911 a law was enacted fixing 60 per cent as the maximum per centage permissible, and authorize cities and towns to reduce the assessment of buildings below this figure, buying not more than 15 per cent per annum. Regina, the capital city, at once took advantage of the act, so that in 1915 buildings were entirely exempted from taxation. Practically all the towns and cities are following the same policy.

The movement for the exemption of improvements has spread eastward into Manitoba and Ontario. The rural districts of Manitoba confine taxation largely to lands, and the capital, Winnipeg, since 1909, has exempted one-third of the value of buildings. In Ontario three hundred municipalities have petitioned for power to reduce taxes on improvements. By 23 to 1, the Toronto City Council, in January, 1913, submitted to the citizens the question of exempting buildings, whereupon the citizens voted in the affirmative four to one.


IV. NEW ZEALAND[3]


Since 1891 New Zealand has levied a separate tax on land values which in 1915 was at the rate of 1d in the pound of the unimproved value. In addition to this ordinary tax on all land, from which only a state's worth less than £500 are exempt, New Zealand also imposes a graduated tax on large estates. The purpose of this graduated taxes to break up the large estates which obstructed the growth of the country. The tax begins with a rate at 1/32 of a penny in the pound for a state's worth £5000, and increases to 5 5/8d per pound upon estates valued at £200,000 or more. To a considerable extent this graduated tax has accomplished its purpose.

Prior to 1896 local taxes had been levied upon either the capital value or the income a real estate, as each locality might elect. The law of 1891 imposing a state tax on land values, and exclusive of improvements, called attention to the desirability of permitting local governments to raise their taxes in a similar manner. Accordingly in 1896 local bodies were empowered to levy their rates on the unimproved value of land, if they so desired. By 1915 not less than 132 districts had adopted this method of taxing land values, and a British Parliamentary Report of 1906 showed that the result had been satisfactory at every point.[4] Concerning the working of this method the Commissioner of Taxes of New Zealand wrote in 1906: "The tendency of this system of taxation is not to increase rent, but, on the contrary, as the tax becomes heavier, it tends to bring into beneficial occupation land not put to its best use, and so reduces rents, the improvements being free from all rates and taxes."


V. NEW SOUTH WALES


New South Wales introduced a state tax on land values in 1895, and subsequently extended this method of taxation into local finance. The following statement recently signed by 90 mayors and aldermen shows the success of the system:

It has reduced the rates of a very large proportion of the ratepayers, although we are raising a larger revenue. It has stimulated the building trade, employment is more consistent, and business generally is on a much sounder footing. It is induced a number of ratepayers to build, or dispose of land which they were not able or willing to use themselves..... It's specially benefits those ratepayers whose use of land is most effective and creditable to the municipality, while it has put off effective pressure upon a number of owners of idle or partially used land to change their tactics.[5]

It is not surprising, therefore, that in 1915, with a few trifling exceptions, that 189 local authorities impose their local rates exclusively upon land values.


VI. SOUTH AUSTRALIA


South Australia introduced a state tax on unimproved land values in 1884, at the uniform rate of 1/2d in the pound. Ten years later an additional 1/2d was imposed on estates valued at more than £5000, and upon estates owned by absentees an additional tax was levied at the rate of one fifth of the tax otherwise payable. Though intermediate changes have been made, the rates of 1884 and 1894 now stand. One-fifth of the tax revenue of the state is obtained from this source.

More recently South Australia has authorized local governments to impose their taxes upon land values exclusively, exempting not only buildings, fences and drains, but all forms of personal property. Eight municipalities have adopted this system and it is hoped that others will follow.


VII. OTHER AUSTRALIAN STATES


Every state in Australia except Queensland now has in some form tax on land values. Queensland raises its local revenues wholly from taxes on land values; while Western Australia and Victoria have made a beginning in this direction.


VIII. THE COMMONWEALTH OF AUSTRALIA


In 1910 the federal government of Australia adopted a federal tax upon the land value of all estates having an unimproved value in excess of £5000. The constitutionality of this act was assailed before the high court of Australia, but without success.

In spite of the high exemption provided for by the law and the difficulties of carrying out the valuation at assessment over the whole extent of Australia, the tax has yielded more than £1,300,003. Since the beginning of the war the land tax has been increased to yield £1,000,000 additional revenue.


IX. KIAO-CHAU[6]


The first of recent German experiments in taxing the unearned increment, and the one which pointed the way for others, was made in the model German colony of Kiao-Chau which was established in 1897 in China. The land and tax ordinance of 1898 imposed attacks of 33 1/3 per cent of any increment of value accruing thereafter to private purchasers of lands acquired from the government. The purpose was to check land speculation, insure to settlers a reasonable price for land, and secure for the government part of any future increment due to the large expenditures made in establishing and developing the new colony. Provision was made for land tax of 6 per cent on the value of land, exclusive of improvements, and a tax on land sales at auction. This ordinance suddenly and unexpectedly realized the German land reformers' program, in a German colony under the direct control the Imperial government. It naturally aroused great interest in Germany, and soon led to it tends to tax the honor increment in various German cities.


X. GERMAN CITIES


The Prussian law of 1893, regulating local taxation, authorized local governments to introduce an important change in their taxation of land. Prior to that time land had been tax upon its estimated yield, with a result that land held for speculative purposes was very lightly taxed. The law of 1893 authorized localities to change the basis of assessment to the capital value of the land, a change which has been made by several hundred local governments in the face of hostility of speculators and large landowners. The change has worked well in other respects, and has materially increase the taxes paid by unimproved land.

The second step in the direction of heavier taxation of land values has been the introduction in many cities of special taxes on the unearned increment, modeled after the ordinance of Kiao-Chau. Such experiments were found to be authorized by the Prussia law of 1893 regulating local taxation, and since 1904 several other states have taken action in this direction.

Among the cities Frankfurt and Cologne took the lead, introducing increment taxes, respectively, in 1904 and 1905. Their example was rapidly followed by scores of other places, including most of the large cities, until by 1910 the increment tax was an operation in 457 cities and towns and was yielding a substantial revenue. The rate of taxation ranged from 1 per cent to 25 per cent of the amount of the increment.


XI. THE GERMAN EMPIRE


In 1911, after two years of discussion, the German empire introduced in Imperial tax upon the unearned increment. This law imposed a progressive tax, increasing according to the percentage with the increment board to the original value of the land. Then it took 10 of the increment land that amounted to 10 per cent of the original value, and increased 1 per cent for each additional 20 per cent of the increment until it reached 19 per cent on increment ranging from 170 per cent to 190 per cent. From that point it increased 1 per cent for every additional 10 per cent of the increment, until it reached 30 per cent of all increments of 290 per cent and over.

This imperial tax was intended to unify the taxation of the unearned increment throughout the empire and replaced the local increment taxes. To compensate the cities for the revenue thus lost, the law provided that 40 per cent of the product of the imperial increment tax should be apportioned to the local governments; while the states were given 10 per cent and the empire retained 50 per cent. Authority was granted, however, to impose additional rates for local purposes; so that some measure of local option was retained.

In 1913, under pressure of added military burdens, a readjustment of imperial and state revenues was brought about. The unearned increment tax was given back to the state and local governments, and for the benefit of the imperial treasury a new tax, imposing a moderate rate on all increments, earned as well as unearned, was established.


XII. GREAT BRITAIN


The now famous Lloyd George budget of 1909, which finally became a law in 1910, imposed for different taxes upon land, which marked the long step forward in the taxation of land values. The first, and most discussed, was the so-called increment value duty. This imposes a tax of 20 per cent upon land increment arising after 1909; which shall be payable by the owner when land is sold, leased for more than fourteen years, or transferred death. Land held by corporate bodies and not changing hands shall pay the tax every fifteen years. The tax amounts to 20 per cent of the increment that shall have accrued since 1909, or the last time the tax shall have been paid. To carry the law into effect it was necessary, of course, to provide for a full valuation of all the land in Great Britain, in order to determine its value, exclusive improvements, in the year 1909. This work is now under way; and will result in a monumental survey comparable to the Doomsday Book.

The second tax is the reversion duty, which imposes a tax of 10 per cent on increment or benefit accruing to any lessor at the expiration of a lease. Agricultural land is exempt, and leases for twenty-one years or less are also exempted from the operation of the reversion duty. Reversions purchased before 1909 are exempt provided the lease expires within forty years from the date of purchase. Finally provision is made that reversion duty shall not be paid in respect to increment or benefit upon which increment value duty may have been paid.

The third tax is the undeveloped land duty which is payable annually by the owner of undeveloped land. It's rate is half penny in each pound of the site value of such land, the value to be ascertained in 1909 and each fifth year thereafter; and proper allowance will be made for increments of value upon which increment duty may have been paid. Land is to be considered undeveloped if not built on or used for some business other than agriculture. Various exemptions are granted, for instance, to land, the site value of which does not exceed £50 per acre, land kept free from buildings in pursuance of some definite plan of development, and parks, gardens, or open spaces to which the public has access.

The fourth tax is the mineral rights duty, which is levied annually at the rate of 5 per cent on money received by owners for the right to work minerals and for way-leaves. If the owner works the minerals himself, he is required to pay upon what he might have received in rents or royalties.

Since the land valuation has not yet been completed the financial importance of these new taxes cannot be determined. They are very important, however, in establishing a principle and in requiring a valuation all land of Great Britain. When the valuation is completed it is the intention of the tax reformers to move for a reform of local taxation, by which local rates shall be levied exclusively upon land values.


XIII. UNITED STATES


Much progress has been made along administrative lines toward the exemption of improvements. Legislation, moreover, has been enacted in Colorado and Pennsylvania. In 1913 the city of Pueblo, Colorado, taking advantage of the whole rule amendment of 1912, amended its charter so as to provide for the exemption of improvements to the extent of 50 per cent of first-year and 99 per cent thereafter. In 1913 Pennsylvania pass a law, which applies to Pittsburgh and Scranton, providing for the eventual reduction of the rate on improvements by one-half.

While further advance of the movement in the United States is handicapped in most states by legislative constitutional restrictions, it is probably true that a larger percentage of ground rent is reclaimed by the community through taxation in the states of Massachusetts and New York than in any other territory in the world. To get in contrast with these gradual British and colonial attainments, the record of the United States for actual achievement is a comparative blank. This condition in the birthplace and home of the great expounder himself is not easy to account for, except insofar as constitutional requirements of uniformity prevent experiment. In England the fact that the land question has long been far more acute that it is in the United States has had much to do with the more rapid progress of the single tax. The concentration of land ownership in England is unparalleled in the United States. The irritating attaining spectacle of enormous entailed estates, with large areas held for game preserves, and the practical exemption of land from all local taxation, has fomented a state of public opinion favorable to single tax ideas. In the British colonies, the movement for the single tax may be explained in part by reference to the peculiar texture of the colonial mind. The colonists are extremely hospitable to new considerations in receptive to new conclusions, and if only they appear to be sound. Charged with building new dominions, they unconsciously join hands for the realization of what seemed to them the best things in government and state.

More important, however, than any other factor in the practical results of the two cases is the difference between the English and the American methods of procedure. In the British Empire the voters begin at once to discuss among themselves and within themselves the advantages of the land tax, and straightaway, by the very cohesion of a common thought, they set about to get it with, as it were, one heart invoice, by enactment of land laws. In this country the voters are of a different type; they are mostly too busy to concern themselves with making even their own laws. Consequently the cause has been consigned to scattered organizations, which have proceeded to discuss the theoretical possibilities and impossibilities and probabilities of every phase of the land tax question, combined with other questions more or less related, to the end of the catalogue. To a world hungering to know of the doctrine of Henry George a great and efficient lecture bureau bearing his name offers, in a prospectus of 41 lecturers with eight topics that are pure single tax and ninety-two that are not, a composite menu of such conflicting merit, taste, and relevancy that most of the inquiring guests leave the table with small desire to come again. Mr. Thomas G. Shearman lamented that "in all times it has been the misfortune of reforms that some of their advocates have made it impossible for others to do any effective work for them, for considerable periods..... At this time the professed friends of every reform in which I am much interested have insisted upon mixing it with retrograde movements or have adopted a policy of bitterness and vituperation or have thrown it entirely overboard."

This hectic discussion which, it must be admitted, does not enlist a mind of the serious English type, has been perpetual in club, in league, on lecture platform, by spokesman and organs, until the conclusion seems unavoidable that in American centers the more numerous the militant single taxes, the less progress toward the single tax. The record to date in our own country, adjoining the very domains of greatest advance, presents an unenviable contrast. Thus, at the end of a quarter of a century succeeding the George revival that followed his candidacy for mayor of New York in 1886, there is no organized body of people in the United States pledged to the propagation of his doctrine as he taught it. So far as these sporadic methods have prevailed, some have been a positive hindrance and detriment because they have accomplished nothing upon their own desultory lines, but -- what is of infinitely greater import -- they have, by keeping the cause in discredit with the mass of thoughtful people, estopped anything akin to the English movement. Perhaps one of the greatest impediments to the popular consideration of the single tax is the misconception that it involves the abolition of the institution of private property in land. In this connection is significant to observe that in not of the "achievements" noted above has the economic argument for the proposed tax reform been tainted with any suggestion for the disruption of the private ownership of land.

If any one thing is prominently in the evidence, it is that the formal combination of the single tax with political action and methods has been uniformly disastrous to the single tax. When Progress and Poverty was scarcely three years old, its author, under the auspices of Patrick Ford and the Irish World, was drafted into the service of the Irish National Land League to share with Parnell and Davitt and Dillon and O'Kelly their platform, arrest, and jail, in an Irish maelstrom that ended in Fenian outrages, with later an inside view of two Irish bastiles until Henry George wrote, "The whole situation is very bad in perplexing. The Land League on both sides of the water seems to me to be smashed." Meantime the "remedy" of Henry George, as applied in book VIII of Progress in Poverty, had not been at all in issue. Henry George was called to Ireland, not to preach union upon his own peculiar doctrine, but to boom conflicting views of nationalization by purchase, abolition without compensation, etc. "With all leaders saved Davitt and Brennan hostile to him in principle, Henry George felt increasingly lonely in the Irish movement." Not a point was scored then or since for the single tax, in respect to which the Irish movement to date has been a retrogression rather than an advance.

In this case of Ireland, Mr. George and his Progress and Poverty were widely advertised, but this advantage, such as it was, was far more than offset by a lowered moral plane, especially when a fresh single-tax "flag for all nations" was bedraggled in the mire. It is difficult to see how this Irish experience could have otherwise than marred the prestige of Progress in Poverty and its author, who was at this time "next to Gladstone the most talked of man in England," and at this sober distance we may be excused for sympathizing with his venerable parents, whom he was called to mourn at this time. "They had died when their son Henry was getting, so far as they could see, as much blame as praise from the world. The peril of the single tax in England today, as it was in Ireland, lies in trying prematurely to make it a political issue, instead of letting it win its own way.

The supreme political event in Mr. George's life was, of course, and his first candidacy for mayor of New York. The labor unions united upon him, not as a single-tax candidate on a single-tax platform, but in the hope that his fame might win out for them. Roosevelt had 60,000 votes and George had 68,000, while Hewitt obtained 90,000 and was elected. The failure to receive a majority of votes did not represent all of Mr. George's loss. He lost infinitely more through campaign misrepresentation, vituperation, and distortion of his doctrine by ignorant but well-meaning friends as well as by foes. It must be a bold historian who would venture to say that Henry George and his cause stood any higher with a world after than before this bitter campaign.

Again, the following year found him the hopeful candidate of the United Labor Party for Secretary of State, in confusion in conflict, especially with socialist persons and parties. The Republican and Democratic candidates, without particular canvass, received 459,000 and 480,000 votes, respectively. Mr. George, with a thorough canvass, received 72,000 for the state and 38,000 for the city of New York as again 68,000 only a year before. This inflation and collapse, in one short year, of a political party movement, did not look like victory for a great economic truth, and yet the confident assertion was made that the "hand of the Lord" was in it. No one recalled that the lord was not in the whirlwind or in the earthquake or in the fire, but in "a still small voice;" no one protested that in order to usher in a heavily reform it was not necessary first to "raise hell."

The Delaware campaign begun in 1895, in which Philadelphia, with the cooperation Mr. George, Mr. Garrison, and the leading speakers of the cause, aided by liberal contributions in money, essayed for more than two years to carry that state by election, for the single tax proved a disappointment and has had no effect upon subsequent legislation. The year 1897 found Mr. George again a candidate for mayor of New York, but upon a platform in which his own peculiar doctrine was not given the recognition of even a single plank. Henry George's campaign was ended by his death, to which his friends sought he was foredoomed, while the most confident predictions of the great profit, as well as of many a minor profit, still lacked fulfillment, and indeed remain lamentable unrealized to this day.

Recently political methods have once more been invoked in connection with the expenditure of hundreds of thousands of most generous money and much vigorous and unselfish effort by speakers and organizers to carry elections in Missouri, Washington, Oregon, and other parts of the country. With what result? -- that today in those regions the press is closed and the farmers' minds are closed, and that both will be so much the harder to open in the future. Can any Englishman be blamed for concluding that if Canada had been subjected for the last twenty years to the mode or procedure which has prevailed in the States, she would not now stand as she does at the head of the single-tax column?

We have thus passed in brief review a series of vigorous American political movements extending over thirty hopeful years, and yet today, while gratifying economic harvests are being reaped upon British soils that have been patiently and yet quietly tilled, not an achievement is registered for the American method, which so far has consisted mainly in lining men up on every other issue except the specific teaching of Henry George.

In conclusion, it cannot be gainsaid that the political method as a means of putting the single tax on the statute books has been abundantly tried and found wanting, and the reasons for its failure are not far to seek. Voters cannot be persuaded to decree an important legislative innovation which they do not fully understand and concerning which it is easy for the opposition, in the heat of the campaign, to deceive or confuse the mind. Moreover, the inevitable mingling of extraneous issues and personal interests with the economic point which is sought to be enforced, is certain so to obscure the single tax in any political contest that it must fail to obtain the consideration necessary to a fair verdict at the polls.

So much for what ought not to have been done; and now what is it that ought to be done? In answer, it may be said that the sum total of experience in the thirty years under review enforces the conviction that the persistent education of the masses and the classes -- by word-of-mouth and still more effectively by the printing press -- upon the pure issue of the single tax as the normal and just basis for obtaining public revenue, is the true means and method of advancing this or any other great reform. To sow the clean seed broadcast and to give time an opportunity for its unforced growth in receptive minds, this is the one irresistible, because unresisted, modus operandi -- this is the surest as well as shortest path to the triumph of that economic justice which will solve our economic problems.

FOOTNOTES

  1. The facts concerning Canada have been taken largely from the "Vancouver number" of the Single Tax Review, May-June, 1912 (150 Nassau St, New York); and Provincial and Local Taxation in Canada, by S. Vineberg (New York, 1912).
  2. On Alberta, in addition to references previously given, see Single Tax Review, September-October, 1911.
  3. See the "New Zealand number" of the Single Tax Review, September-October, 1912, and Land Values, June, 1915.
  4. Papers Relative to the Taxation of the Unimproved Value of Land in New Zealand, New South Wales, and South Australia, Cd. 3191 (1906).
  5. Land Values, p. 19 (June, 1915).
  6. See article by Dr. W. Schrameier in Single Tax Review, March-April, 1911.



PREFACE Ch. 1 - Adam Smith
Ch. 2 - John Stuart Mill Ch. 3 - Patrick Edward Dove
Ch. 4 - Edwin Burgess Ch. 5 - John MacDonnell
Ch. 6 - Henry George Ch. 7 - Edward McGlynn
Ch. 8 - Thomas G. Shearman, Pt 1 Ch. 8 - Thomas G. Shearman, Pt 2
Ch. 9 - A Burdenless Tax to the Threefold to Support Upon Which the Single Tax Rests Ch. 10 - Land -- the Rent Concept -- the Property Concept
Ch. 11 - Taxation and Housing Ch. 12 - Thirty Years of Henry George
Ch. 13 - Henry George and the Economists Ch. 14 - The Professors and the Single Tax
Ch. 15 - A Catechism of Natural Taxation ...