.


SCI LIBRARY

A Dialogue on Political Economy


Edward J. Dodson



[A dialogue involving several participants based on the writings of important contributors to the dialogue on "the land question" and economic justice, held in 1982 at the Henry George Institute, New York, NY]


Political economy has undergone intensive analysis for a period of several centuries. And yet , all the writings and discussion generated have yet to produce a consensus of thought on the political and economic problems experienced by the world's societies What you are about to read is the result of research into the writings of some of the world's most learned and respected contemporary and historical personalities in the realm of political economy. Their ideas are brought together in the form of a dialogue, as though they were seated all in a room engaging in a substantive debate. The role of "moderator" has been created to stimulate and guide this exchange.


MODERATOR

Welcome to this roundtable discussion on the subject of political economy. Our guests include some well-respected authorities on political economy and spokesmen for certain particular points of view where policies, prescriptions and issues are concerned. With us today are Robert L. Heilbroner, Adam Smith, Karl Marx, Henry George, Lester C. Thurow, John Maynard Keynes, Gunnar Myrdal, C. Lowell Harris, Arthur Laffer and (although he represents more of a political than economic perspective), former President of the United States, John Adams.

I would like to begin our discussion by asking Professor Heilbroner to comment on what has been a very long and unsuccessful search for solutions he has himself termed "the Economic Problem." Professor Heilbroner?

ROBERT HEILBRONER

Thank you. As a starting point to this discussion, I would suggest to my colleagues that the trouble with economics is that it will not stand still. Issues change, ideas change, understanding changes . Even the past does not look exactly the same from one year to the next, and the present is apt to alter almost out of all recognition. [1]

MODERATOR

How, then, Professor Heilbroner, is one to approach the study of political economy in a manner which has a reasonable opportunity to produce understanding?

ROBERT HEILBRONER

I would emphasize a broad understanding of economic history -- not, of course, to learn names and dates, but to gain a sense of the evolution of the economic system, of the internal changes that have gradually altered the setting of economic life, and of the trajectory of economic evolution. [2]

MODERATOR

Your comments on the importance of understanding economic history are ones with which I believe any of your colleagues would agree. It strikes me that the most significant changes first occurred during that time period when the last remnants of feudalism in the European-centered economy were losing ground to the merchants of the nation-states and "capitalism." Economic historians have pointed to the 16th century for evidence of this process of change. Do you see this period, Professor Heilbroner, as a period of major change?

ROBERT HEILBRONER

Yes, of course. Let me address for a moment these issues of historical change and the growth in the role of government. In antiquity and feudal times one could not easily separate the economic motivations or even the economic actions of the great mass of men from the normal round of existence itself. The peasant following his memorial ways was hardly conscious of acting according to "economic" motivations; indeed, he did not: he heeded the orders of his lord or the dictates of custom. Nor was the lord himself economically oriented. His interests were military or political or religious, and not basically oriented toward the idea of man or increase. The making of money was a tangential rather than a central concern of ancient or medieval existence. [3]

One further comment, if I may. An essential part of the evolution of the market society was thus not only the monetization of life but the mobilization of life -- that is, the dissolution of ties of place and station which were the very cement of feudal existence. And this essential requirement of mobility lends to a further point. Mobility meant that any job or activity was now open to all comers. Competition appeared. Now any worker and any employer could be displaced form his task by a competitor who would do the job more cheaply.

MODERATOR

Gentlemen, Professor Heilbroner has presented several rather direct statements concerning the development of political economy as an historical process. I'd like to first ask our Scottish colleague, Adam Smith, who we all know as the author of the economic treatise The Wealth of Nations, how his analysis of these historical processes compares with those of Professor Heilbroner.

ADAM SMITH

Well, now. What Professor Heilbroner seems to be saying, without really saying it, is something about the nature of man and the nature of political economy which which I can agree. Approaching the historical evolution of the subject somewhat differently, I would spread the science of economics into two general divisions, which may be named natural economics and political economics. Let me explain what I mean by this separation. The first observes and records the behavior of the human race in obtaining its necessary sustenance, as it could reasonably be expected when not interfered with nor diverted by any outside force. This, however, is a state which does not actually exist anywhere in the civilized world. The organization of a civilized society supposes some impairment of individual rights, and some restraint of natural individual impulses and desires. Until human nature becomes perfect, such restraints are necessary; the problem is to keep them within the narrowist possible limits. [5]

MODERATOR

That, Professor Smith, has remained a largely unresolved issue even through the present day. This argument over the proper role of the "state" in the political economy is one of crucial importance. Your ideas, Professor Smith lie at one end of the theoretical spectrum; at the other, perhaps, are those of Karl Marx. Herr Marx, how do you view the question of individual rights, the power of the state and what best responds to human nature?

KARL MARX

Pardon me, please, if I bypass this question for the moment. I, too, would like to comment on the historical processes involved in the evolution of human society. I would simply add, here, that even when a society has got upon the right track for the discovery of the natural laws of its movement it can neither clear by bold leaps, nor remove by legal enactments, the obstacles offered by the successive phases of its normal development. But it can shorten and lessen the birth-pangs. [6] That is all I wish to say.

MODERATOR

What you've done, I believe, Herr Marx, is to move our discussion into another area of historical disagreement where the study of political economy is concerned. You seem to have equated change with progress. One of your contemporaries, Mr. Henry George (who is best known for his monumental work Progress and Poverty, attempted to distinguish between these two concepts. How, Mr. George, would you react to Herr Marx on this issue?

HENRY GEORGE

Today or a hundred years ago, when I wrote Progress and Poverty, are much the same. Time has passed, change has occurred, but have progress really resulted? By simple observation, I recognized that wealth had been greatly increased, and that the average of comfort, leisure, and refinement had been raised; however, it was true then and is true today that these gains are not general. In them the lowest class do not share. I do not mean that the condition of the lowest class has nowhere nor in anything been improved; but that there is nowhere any improvement which can be credited to increased productive power. I mean that the tendency of what we call material progress is in nowise to improve the condition of the lowest class in the essentials of healthy, happy human life. Nay, nor, that it is still further to depress the condition of the lowest class The new forces, elevating in their nature though they be, do not act upon the social fabric from underneath, as was for a long time hoped and believed, but strike it at a point intermediate between top and bottom. It is as though an immense wedge were being forced, not underneath society, but through society. Those who are above the point of separation are elevated, but those who are below are crushed down.[7]

MODERATOR


Does this imply, Mr. George, that like Karl Marx you also see the process ending in an inevitable struggle of one class against the other?

HENRY GEORGE

With all due respect to Herr Marx and the large following he has secured, his analysis is materially flawed because he fails to properly distinguish between ownership "classes" which are productive, and therefore advance the progress of society, and those which are nonproductive. By its very nature ownership of capital must involve production in order to generate new wealth. Ownership of land, on the other hand, requires no such ownership activity, only the growth of the community. What Professor Heilbroner terms the "economic problem" can be largely solved by giving labor a free field and its full earnings; take for the benefit of the whole community that fund which the growth of the community creates, and want and the fear of want would be gone. The springs of production would be set free, and the enormous increase of wealth would give the poorest ample comfort The progress of science, the march of invention, the diffusion of knowledge, would bring their benefits to all. [8]

MODERATOR

So, in your opinion, Mr. George, the real struggle is not between labor and capital; rather, labor and capital are united in a bitter struggle against the landowners. Is that a fair restatement?

HENRY GEORGE

Yes, I have no objection to your summary of my comments. I would, however, like to hear Herr Marx's response; that is, if he has one.

MODERATOR

Herr Marx?

KARL MARX

Thank you. Viewed from the present, one cannot but marvel at the improvements in the conditions now experienced by a substantial number of workers in the capitalist societies . To what can be this credited? To the generousity of capitalists? To the productivity of labor? Or, perhaps, to the organization of labor into powerful political and economic voices? Long before the period of Modern Industry, cooperation and the concentration of the instruments of labor in the hands of a few, gave rise, to great, sudden, and forcible revolutions in the modes of production, and consequentially, in the conditions of existence, and the means of employment of the rural populations. I concede to Mr. George that this contest at first took place more between the large and the small landed proprietors, than between capital and wage-labor; on the other hand, when the laborers are displaced by the instruments of labor, by sheep, horses, etc., in this case force is directly resorted to in the first instance as the prelude to the industrial revolution. The laborers are first driven from the land. Land grabbing on a great scale is the first step in creating a field for the establishment of agriculture on a great scale. [9]

MODERATOR

What Mr. George seems to be saying, Herr Marx, is that the capitalist as capitalist is not necessarily the culprit. Certainly, the motivations of the various competing groups during the sixteenth century were many -- the struggle for power between the feudal lords and the monarchies, the conflict between Protestantism and the Pope, the formation of nation-states, the beginnings of colonialism -- and all played a role. What Mr. George concludes, however, is that a general concentration of control over land among nobles of an earlier era and other interests today lies at the heart of this class struggle. Over time, many of the large landowner families has increased their power by also actively accumulating large quantities of available capital.

Let's hear from British economist John Maynard Keynes on this question of distribution. Lord Keynes, is there such a thing as the potential for an equitable distribution of wealth in a capitalist economy?

JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES

Mr. George and others may not agree, but one thing we must recognize is that under the system of "Laissez-faire" and an international gold standard such as was orthodox in the latter half of the nineteenth century, there was no means open to a government whereby to mitigate economic distress at home except through the competitive struggle for markets. [10]

Having said that, I certainly agree that the outstanding faults of the economic society in which we live are its failure to provide full employment and its arbitrary and inequitable distribution of wealth and incomes. However, it must be said that since the end of the nineteenth century significant progress towards the removal of the very great disparities of wealth and income has been achieved through the instrument of direct taxation -- income tax and surtax and death duties -- especially in Great Britain.[11]

MODERATOR

You see the intervention of government through taxes on income and wealth as an appropriate approach to the distribution problem, then, Lord Keynes?

JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES

I strongly believe so.

MODERATOR

Though there may be others, I suspect one member of our group in particular may strongly disagree, Professor Arthur Laffer of the University of California, and architect of what has come to be called "supply-side" economic theory. Professor Laffer, would you care to respond to Lord Keynes?

AUTHOR LAFFER

To begin with, I strongly believe the demand side policies which had been applied in their entirety did not avert the economic collapse of the mid-1970s and in my view actually brought it about. The most damaged by the contraction were the disenfranchised members of society, including minorities, youths and the chronically disadvantaged. [12]

MODERATOR

If the demand management policies originally developed by Lord Keynes during the "Great Depression" are inappropriate, what will work?

ARTHUR LAFFER

Basically, people don't work to pay taxes but instead work to receive something after tax. Likewise, businesses don't invest as a matter of social conscience but do so to make an after-tax return on their investments. It is axiomatic that when more of a good is produced its price falls. Tax rate reductions do lead to more production and if combined with a good monetary policy should reduce inflation. [13]

MODERATOR

Another guest, C. Lowell Harriss of Columbia University, has been involved in some rather significant research with the Tax Foundation, and I would like to have him comment on your statements Professor Laffer. Professor Harriss?

C. LOWELL HARRISS

Well, research into tax rates indicates that when total taxes are as high as they must be to finance modern levels of spending, tax rates will also be. high enough to influence behavior. But the present practice of imposing rates of around 50 percent on the returns to capital of corporations is scarcely essential A lower rate on a larger base offers an alternative. [14]

MODERATOR

What about that Mr. George? Do you feel as do Professors Laffer and Harris on the importance of the rate of taxation imposed?

HENRY GEORGE

As to the question. of taxation, the mode of taxation is, in fact, quite as important as the amount. [15]

MODERATOR

Gentlemen, the reality of the world has been an absence among even the so-called "advanced" and industrialized societies of a political economy able to produce an adequate standard of living for all, Why do you thing this is so? Yes … Adam Smith.

ADAM SMITH

As the study of political economy has evolved, far too few of those in our profession paid much attention to the lessons taught by history. In every instance, as soon as the land of any country has all become private property, the landlords, like all other men, love to reap where they never sowed, and demand a rent even for its natural produce. The wood of the forest, the grass of the field, and all the natural fruits of the earth, which, when land was in common, cost the laborer only the trouble of gathering them, come, even to him, to have a price fixed upon them. The man who cultivates the land must give up to the landlord a portion of what his labor collects or produces. This portion, or, which comes to the same thing, the price of this portion, constitutes the rent of land which must be included in the price of most commodities. [16]

MODERATOR

What about those societies where private ownership of land has been eliminated, as in most of the communist-run societies?

ADAM SMITH

I'm willing to address this point; however, I'd like to hear from someone here who actually had to face the issue of private property in land as a basic political issue.

MODERATOR

And who is that, Professor Smith?

ADAM SMITH

Well, within this gathering I suggest we hear from one of America's original founding fathers and former President of the new nation, John Adams.

MODERATOR

President Adams?

JOHN ADAMS

I, too, believe that property in the soil is the natural foundation of power and authority. Three cases of soil ownership are supposable. First, if the prince own the land he will be absolute. All who cultivate the soil, holding it at this pleasure, must be subject to his will. Second, here the landed property is held by a few men the real power of the government will be in the hands of an aristocracy or nobility, whatever they are named. Third, if the lands are held and owned by the people and prevented from drifting into one or a few hands, the true power will rest with the people, and that government will, essentially, be a Democracy, whatever it may be called. Under such a constitution the people will constitute the State. [17]

MODERATOR

To which form of land ownership would you ascribe communism as practiced in the modern era?

JOHN ADAMS

One may draw one's own conclusions based on the extent to which political and individual freedoms also exist.

MODERATOR

And yet, the protection of property rights was an extremely important issue behind the conflict between the American colonies and its mother country, England. Why, then, is the private accumulation of land such an important element to you, Mr. George, and the others here who represent the classical perspective on political economy?

HENRY GEORGE

The long-term effects are best illustrated by the constant existence of speculation where private ownership has been protected by the governing authority. Essentially, the influence of speculation in land in increasing rent is a great fact which cannot be ignored in any complete theory of the description of wealth in progressive countries. It is the force, evolved by material progress, which tends constantly to increase rent in a greater ratio than progress increases production, and thus constantly tends, as material progress goes on and productive power increases, to reduce wages, not relatively, but absolutely. It is this expansive force which, operating with great power in new countries, brings to them, seemingly long before their time, the social diseases of older countries. In short, the general and steady advance in land values in a progressive community necessarily produces that additional tendency to advance which is seen in the case of commodities when any general and continuous cause operates to increase their price. [18]

GUNNAR MYRDAL

Thank you very much, Mr. George. As you suggest, findings in a study we did on Southeast Asia in the late l960s revealed there are other factors that, by keeping down the labor productivity, together are responsible for low average incomes and low standards of life. Very low living levels decrease the amount of labor input and also the intensity and efficiency of the work actually performed on the land by the labor force. Low incomes are only the other side of low labor productivity; a vicious cycle makes poverty and low levels of living, or low labor productivity; self-generating.

Behind this unfortunate causal mechanism there is a social system of institutions and power relations, that is severely inimical to productivity, at the same time as low productivity establishes itself as the norm. And within this social system, both shaped by it and upholding it, are the ingrained attitudes of people in all classes. Among the non-physical factors that keep down labor productivity are also the primitive techniques employed in agriculture, likewise both a function of the existing social system, which deprives the tillers of both capital and incentives to greater effort, and a prop to that system. [19]

MODERATOR

That sounds very much like a prescription for social and political upheaval, which has certainly been the experience in Southeast Asia. Professor Heilbroner, can you add anything to Gunnar Myrdal's statement?

ROBERT HEILBRONER

In my view the prerequisite for economic progress for the underdeveloped countries today is not essentially different from what it was in Great Britain at the time of the industrial revolution, or what it was in Russia in 1917. To grow, an underdeveloped economy must build capital. [20]

MODERATOR

How important to capital building are these social and political factors discussed by both Gunnar Myrdal and Henry George?

ROBERT HEILBRONER

Very important, obviously. How is a starving country to build capital when 80 percent of its people are scrabbling on the land for a bare subsistence? The crowding of peasants on the land has resulted in a diminution of agricultural productivity far below that of the advanced countries. Hence the abundance of peasants working in the fields obscures the fact that a smaller number of peasants, with little more capital could raise a total output just as large. By raising the productivity of the tillers of the soil, a work force can be made available for the building of roads and dams, while this "transfer" to capital building need not result in a diminution of agricultural output. [21]

MODERATOR

Is this a realistic approach to a solution, Professor Heilbroner, when there is so much political turmoil in most of these countries?

ROBERT HEILBRONER

Understand that what I have outlined is not a formula for immediate action. In many underdeveloped lands, the countryside already crawls with unemployment, and to create overnight, a large and efficient farming operation would create an intolerable social situation. We should think of the process as a long-term blueprint which covers the course of development over many years. It shows us that the process of development takes the form of a huge internal migration from agricultural pursuits, where labor is wasted, to industrial and other pursuits, where it can yield a net contribution to the nation's progress. [22]

MODERATOR

The problem I see in your statement is that even in the developed, industrialized capitalist economies unemployment and underemployment remain as major problems. And, government redistributive programs have not addressed the issue of creating productive employment opportunities. Not much time remains, but I would like to hear from Lester Thurow, whose book Zero Sum Society attempts to deal with this. Professor Thurow?

LESTER THUROW

To have no government programs for redistributing income is simply to certify de facto that the existing market distribution of incomes is equitable. One way or another, we are forced to reveal our collective preferences about the "just" distribution of economic resources. As a result, one basic responsibility of government in a market economy is to create an equitable distribution of income and wealth if it has not been produced by the market.[23]

MODERATOR

What do you see as the role of the political economist in light of the increasing dependence upon government to achieve some degree of economic justice?

LESTER THUROW

My feeling is that although modern economics springs from the search for a definition of economic justice, it has largely abandoned that search. Thus, nineteenth century economists, such as John Stuart Mill and our other historical colleagues, spent much of their time searching for the principles that would lead to a condition of equity. But by the l940s, economists reluctantly came to the conclusion that there were no economic statements that could be made about equity. [24]

MODERATOR

Would you agree, Mr. George, with Lester Thurow's conclusion that equity is an illusionary economic concept?

HENRY GEORGE

I have written, and still believe, that the association of poverty with progress is the great enigma of our times. It is the central fact from which spring industrial, social, and political difficulties that perplex the world, and which statesmanship and philanthropy and education grapple in vain. From it come the clouds that overhang the future of the most progressive and self-reliant nations. So long as all the increased wealth which modern progress brings goes but to build up great fortunes, to increase the luxury and make sharper the contrast between the House of Have and the House of Want, progress is not real and cannot be permanent. To educate men who must be condemned to poverty, is but to make them restive; to pass on a state of most glaring social inequality and political institutions under which men are theoretically equal, is to stand a pyramid on its apex. [25]

MODERATOR

Thank you Mr. George. Time has elapsed, so I hope this discussion has for all of you been as informative and enlightening as it has for me.


REFERENCES


  1. Robert L. Heilbroner, The Economic Problem, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, 1970, Preface v.
  2. Ibid., ix.
  3. Ibid., pp.59-60.
  4. Ibid., p.65.
  5. Arthur Hugh Jenkins, Adam Smith Today, Richard R Smith Co., New York, 1948, p. 25.
  6. Karl Marx, Capital, The International Publishers Co., New York, Reprinted 1939. Author's Prefaces xviii-xix.
  7. Henry George, Progress and Poverty, Robert Schalkenbach Foundation, New York, Reprinted 1954. pp. 8-9.
  8. Ibid., p. 461.
  9. Marx, p. 430.
  10. John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York, Reprinted 1964, p. 382.
  11. Ibid., pp. 372-373.
  12. Arthur B. Laffer, "Reagan's Policies a Sound Departure", Los Angeles Times, July 8, 1981.
  13. Ibid.
  14. C. Lowell Harriss, "Taxation of Business: Fundamental Issues", Essays on Taxation, Tax Foundation Inc., New York, 1974, p. 52.
  15. Henry George, p. 409.
  16. Arthur Hugh Jenkins, p. 60.
  17. John Adams, Works, Volume III, p. 466.
  18. Henry George, p. 259.
  19. Gunnar Myrdal, Asian Drama, Volume I, Pantheon Books, 1968, p. 433.
  20. Heilbroner, p. 640.
  21. Ibid., p. 641.
  22. Ibid.
  23. Lester C. Thurow, "Toward A Definition of Economic Justice", The Public Interest, No. 31 (Spring 1973), p. 82.
  24. Ibid., p. 82.
  25. Henry George, p. 10.