.


SCI LIBRARY

Challenges to the Global Monetary Structure
PART ONE

Edward J. Dodson


[1990]

Abstract


The last decade of the twentieth century and beyond promises to be a period during which the private desires of individuals and groups challenge the system of nation-states that has characterized our socio-political arrangements since the late Renaissance period. The era of empire-building, of centralizing bureaucracies and (more recently) of ideologically-driven alliances faces -- if not extinction -- certainly serious erosion. Our values as well as our systems of production and finance have already become substantially transnational and decentralized, so much so that efficiencies in the sphere of production are more often hampered than assisted by the inherently protectionist policies of the nation-state, acting under its claims to sovereignty.

Despite serious animosities that clearly remain between groups (both within and without individual societies), we are gradually being forced to come to terms with an earth where geopolitical isolation no longer exists as protection for status quo arrangements. Narrow, domestic political and economic considerations cannot dominate the relations between peoples in an interdependent world. The global balance of power is, in fact, less attached to direct coercive influence than ever before in the modern era. Economic power, which in decades past depended to a large extent on a military presence, is now far more the result of providing others with high quality goods and services at affordable prices.

The ownership and control over natural resources, over improved and as yet unimproved building sites, over production facilities and communication systems, and over financial institutions is already transnational. Self-interest, therefore, serves to mitigate the conflict-based quest for hegemony historically pursued by leaders of the nation-state. One cannot, however, ignore the continued maldistributions of income and wealth ownership within societies, and the statistical evidence suggests a widening of the gap in all societies between the haves and the have nots.

In no arena of human endeavor is the process and experience of transnationalism more important than within the global monetary structure. What stands in the way of progress toward a system operated according to just principles, however, is the issuance by governments of legal tender in lieu of the circulation of sound money. This last great vestige of state monopoly power is, nevertheless, also being challenged by transnational organization. This paper examines the historical development of this challenge and speculates on how the displacement of state control over the global medium of exchange will affect the nation-state and our more diverse systems of socio-political arrangements.

Introduction


If history deals in any sense with absolute truth, the basis for such knowledge is to be found in human behavior that is consistent over time and across space. Armed with this type of understanding, we come as close as possible to acquiring the basis for establishing scientific principles where the study of human behavior is concerned. Moreover, because the most consistent of our actions have been those associated with our desire for survival, we can learn much from an examination of these actions throughout our history.

We have for at least tens of thousands of years been engaged in the production and exchange of wealth. (The term wealth is defined for purposes of this examination as anything yielded from nature (i.e., the earth) by human labor -- alone or assisted by physical capital -- that is material and has potential or demonstrated value in exchange.)

Yet, there has also been a darker side to our actions, revealed by our use of coercion and exploitation of others in the pursuit of wealth and power. As the earliest hunter-gatherer groups acquired an understanding of weaponry and as the discovery of agriculture led to fixed settlement, socio-political arrangements within groups evolved to institutionalize a division of labor between the warrior-protectors and the producers of food and other goods. Eventually (and perhaps inevitably) this new division of labor was replaced by a hierarchy of power with the warriors and spiritual (i.e., knowledge-bearing) subgroups at the top and those actually engaged in wealth production at the bottom. As time went on, a third subgroup -- the exchangers -- emerged in many societies to challenge and/or share power.

By the beginning of the nation-state era, the above-described hierarchy had in many societies become extremely sophisticated and deeply-entrenched. In his examination of group hierarchies, sociologist Gerhard E. Lenski concluded:

If anything, inequalities in power and privilege seem usually somewhat less pronounced in mature industrial societies than in agrarian. In short, the appearance of mature industrial societies marks the first significant reversal in the age-old evolutionary trend toward ever increasing inequality.

Professor Lenski's conclusion draws attention to the problems created by increasing complexity in the socio-political arrangements of an industrializing society. Productivity gains from the use of machinery and better organization generally yield certain absolute improvements in the general level of well-being; however, this does not necessarily equate to a lessening of inequality as measured by a distribution of economic, social and political power.

Socio-political arrangements were sanctioned by tradition, by formalization into systems of positive law and by coercive imposition by means of physical domination. Running parallel to the social and political hierarchy has been, of course, a hierarchy of economic power. One means by which these two forms of power were consolidated was control over access to nature; another was control over the medium of exchange.

The scope of this paper neither permits nor demands an historical overview of the use of various commodities and eventual adoption of silver and gold as the preferred mediums of exchange and storehouses of value. Rather, I offer evidence on behalf of the thesis that those in power have consistently exploited the governed, including (when possible) the citizens of other societies, by manipulation and control of a monetary system created to advance centralized power and to sanction what amounts to a pervasive pattern of theft of wealth from producers.

The essential ingredient has been the power of the state and of banks to self-create credit. The consequences of this assumed power have been the confiscation of wealth from producers not only by direct taxation, but also by the issuance of legal tender which (unlike certificates of deposit for coinage or bullion) give to the bearer no specific claim to wealth of a given quantity and quality. Rather, legal tender acquires exchange value because of the coercive imposition of the power of the state.

Monetary Hierarchy


Beginnings

As the consolidating European states fought for control over their own continent and much of the rest of the earth's land mass and sea lanes, the Dutch emerged in the early seventeenth century newly independent from Spain and fast becoming overseers of a far-flung commercial empire in their own right. At least part of their success can be credited to the role they played in reforming what was at the time the global monetary structure. The Scottish philosopher and political economist, Adam Smith, wrote of the Dutch accomplishment:

Before 1609 the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign coin, which the extensive trade of Amsterdam brought from all parts of Europe, reduced the value of its currency about nine percent below that of good money fresh from the mint. Such money no sooner appeared than it was melted down or carried away, as it always is in such circumstances. ...

In order to remedy these inconveniences, a bank was established in 1609 under the guarantee of the city. This bank received both foreign coin, and the light and worn coin of the country at its real intrinsic value in the good standard money of the country, deducting only so much as was necessary for defraying the expence of coinage, and the other necessary expence of management. For the value which remained, after this small deduction was made, it gave a credit in its books. This credit was called bank money, which, as it represented money exactly according to the standard of the mint, was always of the same real value, and intrinsically worth more than current money.

This brief period during which the Bank of Amsterdam served as an international bank of deposit was, I suggest, the high-water mark for sound money in the modern era. Unfortunately, the bankers soon discovered they needed only fractional reserves of bullion or coinage to satisfy the demands by depositors. They then began issuing additional bank notes as loans to business and government borrowers. As this practice became common knowledge, both the certificates of deposit and bank notes lost their full face value in exchange and were traded at a discount.

Over time, the vicissitudes of empire-building, warfare and commercial ventures generated increasing losses for the Bank of Amsterdam, finally forcing its closing in 1819. More important than its eventual demise, however, a narrow window of opportunity for a sound and honest paper currency had long before already disappeared. Bankers as a group made no attempt to return to a full reserve system; fractional reserve banking gave birth to the so-called gold standard, within which the primary skill of both banks and governments was to promote an atmosphere of confidence so that depositors would rather hold paper currency than bullion or coinage. When confidence disappeared, the banks periodically closed their doors at tremendous personal loss to depositors. Until very recently, few governments provided any protection to depositors against such losses.

The Dutch and English battled throughout the mid-seventeenth century for commercial and financial hegemony at the core of an industrializing Europe. In the end, a combination of superior naval power, a more dynamic societal structure and more effective isolation from continental intrigues lifted Britain to a position of dominance within the European hierarchy of nation-states. Most other European states relied heavily on loans from Europe's powerful banking families, the fortunes of which fortunes rose and fell with that of individual monarchs. Britain was unique in that a considerable portion of the cost of empire-building was absorbed by private companies and individuals. Debts by the British monarch were often repaid with sizable grants of land in the Americas and elsewhere, or by monopolistic trading privileges to joint-stock companies. The bankers not only participated in these endeavors but also served as repositories for government funds and as collectors of tax revenue.

By such means, empire-building from the seventeenth century on contributed to the growth of large personal fortunes while, on the whole, impoverishing the overwhelming majority of other citizens. To the extent that opportunities were made available to the producer subgroup, migration to unsettled or conquered territories presented the best opportunity to rise above one's status at birth -- even in Britain. Those closest to the court or (in the case of Britain and a few other states) the parliamentary houses enjoyed tremendous privilege and often wholesale exemption from taxation in support of the central government. Spanish socio-political arrangements represented an extreme example of a society dominated by excessive privilege. Even the vast riches extracted from the Americas were insufficient to defray the cost of maintaining its empire. Enclosures had turned a productive peasantry into landless serfs, and Spain became dependent upon imports not merely for luxuries and manufactures but also for foodstuffs. At the same time, neither the Church nor the aristocracy contributed meaningfully to the costs of empire.

Although the earliest European migrants to the Americas experienced decades of severe hardship and deprivation, those who survived and their offspring benefitted considerably by the access gained to free or very cheap land; in return, they provided vast quantities of foodstuffs and raw materials to European commercial interests. For British subjects in North America, both commerce and self-government prospered for nearly one hundred fifty years under loosely-enforced mercantilist policies. This period of salutary neglect operated to a lesser degree in the French, Dutch and even Spanish colonies; however, the result in British North America was eventual rebellion by a citizenry whose numbers had become large enough to thwart further attempts to impose the rule of empire.

As even Britain was learning, the costs of government merely expanded with the acquisition of new territories or the conquest of other states. Nevertheless, the vested interests of those who benefitted most were repeatedly advanced, regardless of the cost (to others). Not that those in power were totally insensitive to the potential for resistance. Some creativity was demanded to reduce the frequency of such occasions. In a speech made before the House of Lords, William Pitt (the Elder, Earl of Chatham) is quoted as delivering the following statement:

There is a method by which you can tax the last rag from the back, and the last bite from the mouth, without causing a murmur against high taxes, and that is, to tax a great many articles of daily use and necessity so indirectly that the people will pay them and not know it. Their grumbling will then be of hard times, but they will not know that the hard times are caused by taxation.

After breaking from the British empire and a short-lived experience of government under articles of confederation, even the new united states in North America were to suffer a tragic retrenchment from its promise of a decentralized and weak national government. Debts accumulated during the rebellion suggested to some the need for rapprochement with the international bankers and creditors. As a confederation of states, the reference to the "united states" in plural seems appropriate. The assumption at this early date was that the confederation was one based on voluntary association. With the adoption of a federal constitution, this confederation made a quantum leap toward the creation of one nation-state and away from that of a voluntary association. Each state had been issuing its own legal tender, forcing creditors to accept these notes as payment for all debts; outside the individual states, this legal tender was either deeply discounted or not accepted at all. Clearly, successful imposition of a paper currency issued without specific backing required the coercive power only a strong, central government could provide. The influence of merchants and other creditors of the government combined to ensure that the new Federal government would at least assume responsibility for the war debts of the states. The battle between the states, the Federal government and private banks over the issuance of legal tender and bank notes would go on throughout the nineteenth century.

Charles Beard and other historians have painted an interesting picture of how principle was compromised by privilege and vested interest -- couched in terms of necessity -- as the framers came together to forge a new national government over what were still very disunited states. To be sure, there were grave problems facing the new nation, not the least of which was the war debt. Putting the new government's financial affairs in order had to receive high priority, and British prohibitions against the export of bullion or the minting of coinage in North America left the confederation without the basis for establishing a monetary system secured by gold or silver. Historian John C. Miller went so far as to suggest the experience of "[North] Americans under the Articles of Confederation had demonstrated that no government could endure without the ability to borrow.

Extraordinary circumstances do require extraordinary measures, and all newly-emerging nations face both internal and external challenges to their prospects for survival. Nevertheless, there has been far too little debate among economists generally over the systematic effort of those holding power to self-create credit through manipulation of monetary systems. In the United States, this meant violation of the Constitutional provisions under which the Federal government was charged with protecting the citizenry from issuance of unbacked paper currencies. Section 8 of Article I of the Constitution of the United States provides, among other things, that "The Congress shall have Power to ... pay the debts ... borrow Money on the credit of the United States ... [and] coin Money ..." David Ricardo, examining the historical evidence and commenting on contemporary events in Britain, warned his fellow countrymen:

Experience shows that neither a state nor a bank ever has had the unrestricted power of issuing paper money without abusing that power; in all states, therefore, the issue of paper money ought to be under some check and control; and none seems so proper for that purpose as that of subjecting the issuers of paper money to the obligation of paying their notes either in gold coin or bullion.

Although the debate over what constituted sound money would continue within the halls of academia (and, at times, in the chambers of government as well) throughout much of the nineteenth century, the reality of empire-building within the confines of protected privilege left few options open even to those who sought a degree of responsibility where government spending was concerned. The larger the empire, the greater the expenditures for a military and administrative bureaucracy required to preserve (and expand) a nation's holdings and influence. War, when it inevitably comes, very quickly destroys not only human lives but also a large portion of a society's storehouse of physical wealth.

Since the wealthy and powerful are generally unwilling, and the masses unable, to provide government with the coinage or bullion needed to procure the desired quantities of goods and services, the path of least resistance is for governments to issue their own paper currencies. By declaring such notes legal tender for all debts public and private, governments effectively redistribute purchasing power from private citizens to themselves.

Nineteenth century analysts, such as John Stuart Mill (1806-1873) and Henry George (1839-1897) sailed the Ricardian flagship into the twilight of political economy's reign as near-science. Mill thought the substitution of paper currency for coinage and certificates of deposit could be achieved without an inevitable discounting of the paper currency, so long as increases in the quantity thereof were stimulated by the production of real goods and services. The public had to believe that paper currency could be fully converted upon demand; therefore, the function of monetary policy was to maintain confidence even under conditions of minimal actual reserves. This view continues to be put forward by economists who advocate strict monetary rules, such as Milton Friedman. George, for his part, felt the coinage of money was a legitimate function of government but that banking was rightly left to private interests. History, I suggest, argues against such a direct role for any government, as this paper will attempt to demonstrate. In the end, their warnings and denouncements of government policies had little effect. The global monetary system had already evolved into an extension of the nation-state rather than as a system for facilitating exchange between producers.

Viewed outside of the context of the wider socio-political arrangements within which monetary policy functioned, the historian has sometimes been led to rather ironic assertions. Carroll Quigley, for example, saw the resort to fractional reserves as essential during "the great Age of Expansion in the nineteenth century ..." One might ask, however, what the extent of expansion (expansion, defined as the increase in the total stock of physical wealth available for consumption, saving or combination to form new capital) might have been had bank notes not lost their face value as certificates of deposit -- and had the nation-state not co-opted the creation of credit for its own vested interest. Instead the world suffered under the weight of a monetary system by which the industrialized states at the core effectively dominated those less industrialized at the periphery. On this point, the German political scientist Wilhelm Roepke observed in 1937:

The close of the 19th and the beginning of the 20th centuries witnessed ... the successful creation of international monetary homogeneity paralleling that existing on the national level, thanks to the gold standard which united all countries within the framework of one monetary system.

Certainly, this movement toward "one monetary system" was not beneficial to the majority of people throughout the world. Under conditions of open and competitive markets, however, the consequences of monetary homogeneity might have been quite positive. The actual result was characterized by an accelerating maldistribution of wealth in Eurasia that sent tens of millions of people on a mass migration to North America.

Most societies on the Eurasian continent remained dominated by mercantilism and privileged subgroups. In the worst examples, the majority of people lived under conditions of extreme poverty and virtual serfdom (i.e., feudalism without the benefit of feudal obligations to the producers by their overlords). In the monetary arena, the widespread establishment of central banks and legal tender opened the door for organized theft on a scale even the most ardent reformers had failed to anticipate.

PART 2