Taxation Blunders and Their Remedy
Lewis Jerome Johnson
[Reprinted from Harper's Weekly, 12 July,
1913]
One fundamental blunder in our tax system is the assumption that the
public must levy upon private earnings to pay its expenses. This
blunder springs from a failure to realize that the community has a
natural revenue of its own - the annual rental value of the land apart
from improvements. The value in question is simply the value of sites
or locations due to nearness to centres of trade and population, to
the presence of public improvements, to means of transportation and to
various natural advantages. It does not include the value of any
improvements in, on, or under the land. It does not include the
portion of the value of a given piece of land due to the expenditure
of capital or labor on that land. It does include the value of the
franchises of public service corporations. It is relatively very low
in the case of farm-land, and correspondingly high in cities.
This great fund, technically called land value, measures the benefit
conferred by society upon the holders, as such, of titles to land. It
might well be termed the community-made portion of the value of land.
Morally and equitably, it is public property, and should be used to
pay the public expenses, just as an individual's earnings should pay
his individual expenses. Its annual yield has all the characteristics
of an automatic public revenue - except that it will not quite collect
itself into the public treasury. It does, however, flow into plain
sight within easy reach; but our unnatural tax laws permit its
absorption by the individuals who hold land titles - a social blunder
akin to permitting the absorption of the slave's earnings by his "owner."
All we need to do to correct the present-day error is to increase our
present levy upon land values. We would, at the same time, gradually
reduce to extinction all other revenue taxes. Be it observed that this
involves no abandonment of regulative or restrictive taxes, or of
exemptions of land, as at present, in certain cases. Of course, it
leaves our existing system of titles to land unchanged.
The adequacy of land values to meet all public expenses is sometimes
questioned, but not by those who give due weight to the enormous land
values in cities, towns and villages. Be that as it may, however, the
industry which now supports both the government and the landowners
could obviously support the government alone, and with no increase of
load over the present, to say the least!
Note carefully that it is not because land value is "unearned"
by the land-owner that it should go to the public, but because it is
created and earned by the public. This point is sometimes overlooked
even by pretentious "experts," to the great darkening of
their counsel.
How to Undermine Graft. The laws that protect the private absorption
of land values once abolished, and this public fund once turned into
the public treasury where it belongs, all excuse for seizure of
private property under the guise of revenue collection would vanish,
and it is safe to predict that the practice would also disappear. The
abolition of these two legal systems of plunder - that of the
land-owners from the State, and that of the State from the worker -
would strip the skulking graft of the policeman or alderman, and the
smugger plunder of the tariff baron or franchise grabber of their most
potent ally. "Easy money" for some, under the law, suggests
and often even condones "easy money" all along the line, law
or no law. Hence the chaotic state of public morals which makes it so
difficult to get the upper hand of corruption in business and
politics.
Not till the public has learned to recognize and respect its own
property, and to respect that of individuals, can it hope for due
respect on the part of individuals for public property and for one
another's property.
Stopping the Leak Will Unburden Industry. Our present taxing methods
are like transfusing blood into a man's arm while his own blood is
streaming from a strangely unobserved gash in his side. But we have
discovered the hitherto overlooked wound. We are getting ready to
stanch it and perhaps to close it and let the patient thrive upon his
own blood - to his advantage, not to mention those from whom the
transfused blood is drawn. To the extent that we prevent the leakage
of the natural public revenue into private pockets - by the increase
of our present tax on land values - we do away with the need of
transfusion, i. e., with the need of taxing buildings, factories,
stores, machinery, merchandise, railway equipment, live stock,
personal property, and improvements of all kinds. And this, doubtless,
is destined to be the plan of action.
Progress of Land Value Taxation.
The recognition of land values as a public fund, or at least as a
specially appropriate source of public revenue, has in the last
several years made a deep impression on legislation, not only in
British Columbia and in New Zealand, Alberta, Saskatchewan, and
Australia, but in Japan, Germany and England. It is what gives the
Lloyd George Budget its unprecedented social and economic
significance. It has recently been urged in several English by-
elections by Liberal candidates with such striking success that the
taxation of land values can not fail to be adopted soon as a fixed and
leading policy of the Liberal party. So unmistakable is this trend
that even the Pall Mall Gazette (Unionist) of June 28, 1912, declares
that the "Unionist party must set itself to think out and
proclaim a drastic and practical and equitable policy of land reform"
as a counter-move to the Liberal tendency toward the taxation of land
values. In the United States the proposal to exempt all personal
property, buildings, and improvements, with a corresponding increase
upon land values including franchises, has begun to make itself felt
in actual politics. Last fall it was the object of significant, if for
the moment unsuccessful, State-wide campaigns in Missouri and Oregon.
California in the same election cast an encouraging vote for a measure
for municipal home rule in taxation urged with similar intent, a
measure since referred to the people again by an overwhelming vote of
the legislature. The city of Everett, Washington, the fourth city of
the State in size, by a two-to-one vote carrying every ward and
precinct in the city, adopted a measure of this kind, under the label
"Single-Tax Amendment," after carrying it by a slight margin
at the previous election, only to lose it by a court decision on a
technicality. To be sure, office-holders, office-seekers, political
parties, and pretentious "experts" looking only to what they
think are immediate possibilities have, in this country, hardly taken
note of these things as yet. What they have done has been, on the
whole, to be- little or oppose.
But the public is finding small satisfaction in following their past
advice, and is learning to look for leadership to others less hampered
and more far-sighted. The people are hence slowly but surely coming to
see the momentous economic truth that land values properly belong to
the public, and to show their new knowledge in their votes.
"Ability-to-Pay" Doctrine and its Evils. A second blunder
akin to that of failing to recognize in land values a public fund, and
one almost as bad, is the assumption that a tax is justifiable if only
it is in proportion to ability to pay.
The current "ability-to-pay" doctrine fails because it
makes no distinction between ability to pay due to having served the
public and ability to pay due to having plundered the public. It
undertaxes, and thus fosters privilege. It taxes, and thus represses
industry. It makes of taxation a mere system of enforced charity, when
it should be the honest, dignified collection of the public's own
natural revenue. To the extent th.3t this plausible system succeeds in
taxing ability to pay due to useful industry, it is a system of crude
spoliation, or, if you prefer, enforced charity - none the less
demoralizing because legal. It produces the confusion of mind which
leads to the advocacy of income and inheritance taxes as well as taxes
upon personal property and buildings, and thus tends completely to
undermine the security of private property, something it would today
seem wiser to buttress than to weaken.
But the ability-to-pay doctrine has, of course, some truth behind it.
Obviously no tax system could successfully fly in the face of this
doctrine. The dismal failure of the present system is due partly to
the fact that in actual working it falls and is bound to fall with
great disproportionateness upon the poor, and thus flies squarely in
the face of the very principle which in theory is used to justify it.
Let us examine further into the land-value from this point of view.
Would it not prove to be the long-sought tax - one proportioned to the
shoulders that must carry it? A tax on the value of land after
deducting the value of all improvements is primarily and sufficiently
justified as a tax in proportion to benefits conferred by society. It
is merely a payment in proportion to obligation to pay. Land-owners
now get these payments, and, so far as not collected in taxes on land
values, keep them. A tax on this fund, with the discontinuance of all
other revenue taxes, would therefore put taxation on the correct basis
of obligation to pay for value received instead of on the sole basis
of ability to pay. It would also, however, conform to all in the
ability-to-pay principle which is socially or ethically justifiable;
for the holding of land or franchises carries with it, as a matter of
course, ability to pay in proportion as it carries obligation to pay,
precisely as holding a ground lease carries with it the ability as
well as obligation to pay a proper ground rent. And the enormous
private fortunes at which income and inheritance taxes are aimed, with
some show of wisdom, consist in the main of power to absorb land
values, and would thus inevitably be reached by the new tax as far as
they ought to be reached by any tax.
Why the Land-Value Tax is Needed.
Thus the land-value tax meets the dictate of kind feeling that a tax
should in proportion to ability to pay, as well as the inexorable
dictate of morality that it be in proportion to obligation to pay.
Some other merits in the system may be briefly suggested as follows:
Public collection of land values, through taxation would build up a
clear and sound conception of the distinction between public and
private property. It would give us a tax that none could dodge or
shift - a tax that could be assessed and collected with a minimum of
expense, without inquisitorial methods, and with at least a reasonable
approach to fairness and accuracy. We should have a tax having all the
desirable features of income and inheritance taxes without their evil
features. We should have a tax that would not penalize industry,
thrift, or any other socially desirable activity and that would
discourage, instead of fostering, the great social wrong of holding
valuable land out of use or inadequately used.
Effect on Farmers.
Owners of improved real estate, including farms, would usually be
more than reimbursed for the increase of the tax on their land by the
exemption of their buildings and of other improvements on or in the
land, and of personal property not to mention their individual share
in the increasing prosperity. For example, a recent, and doubtless
trustworthy compilation from the official tax-books of Clackmaas
county, Oregon, shows that the 5,407 farmers of that county, exclusive
of tenant farmers and those who hold no improved land - that is, the
working owners of bona-fide farms - would pay 23.91 per cent, less in
taxes on their property if only land values were taxed, the total tax
levy remaining as at present.
To turn to an older community, Massachusetts, we find from recent
valuation (1907, the latest at hand) that in the 284 small towns of
the State (excluding the 70 cities and large towns) only about 20 per
cent, of the whole real estate valuation is community-made, and hence
taxable as land value as denned in this article. That is to say, in
that State, under a system of purely land-value taxation, nearly or
quite 80 per cent, of the value of all rural real estate besides all
the personal property would be exempt from taxation. It is believed,
upon careful analysis, that such a system of taxation, with a proper
distribution of State expenses among the municipalities, would halve
the taxes of Massachusetts farmers. Obviously, a system of taxing only
the community-made values in the land would spell relief for the
working farmer in any part of the country. He is the man who gets the
minimum benefit from society, and is now taxed out of all proportion
to the little benefit he gets - with a tax penalty lying in wait for
every improvement he ventures to make. No wonder his children move to
the city.
The farmer's case has here been given particular consideration,
because he has been known to confound land value with land, and to
assume that, because he has large holdings in land, he would be ruined
by the new system, Misled by this error, he naturally opposes the
proposal to lay all taxes upon land values. Other well- meaning folk
are apt to think he is right, and some not so well meaning have
selfishly encouraged him in his mistake. For his own good and that of
the rest of us, his not unnatural error needs careful pointing out,
and the cause needs the farmer's votes as badly as he needs the cause.
His advantage, in common with other workers, is, of course, clear when
it is realized how very little land value he is now enjoying and how
little of his property would be taxable under the new system. Note
carefully that it is bona-fide working, producing farmers, those who
farm farms rather than farm farmers, of whom we are now speaking. As
to "farmers" who are primarily land-speculators - that is
another story.
Effect on Workers Other Than Farmers.
As for workers other than farmers, their advantage in the change is
even more readily seen. Owning little or no land, valuable or
otherwise, there is no room for the peculiar confusion that besets the
farmer. If a renter of real estate, as is usually the case, he would,
of course, pay the tax on the land that he occupies. He would pay it
as he does now, through his rent payments, payments that are now as
large as the landlord can exact, and that hence could not be increased
by the new tax. The new tax would simply compel the landlord to give
up to the tax collector a larger share than now of the public fund,
land value; while the abolition of the tax on the house, together with
an increased supply of houses, would force down the workers' rent
bill. If the worker owns land, its location value in proportion to his
other property is usually small. Then the removal of taxes on his
necessaries of life - food and clothing, as well as shelter - is
clearly all to his good.
Moreover, all workers, farmers and city workers alike, must gain from
the increased demand for labor and consequent increase of wages
through valuable land coming into use. And the lion's share of the
advantage could no longer go to those whose contribution to the
communal advance consists merely in, owning the land that other people
use.
Who Would Be Hit.
The only persons whose incomes would be diminished, even temporarily,
by putting all revenue taxes on land values would be the few whose
income is derived predominantly from the unnatural right of living off
the public fund, or who persist in injuring society by preventing the
full economic use of valuable land.
Period of Change Not to Be Dreaded.
Like convalescence, the result is all to the good, and will be so
regarded when understood - except perhaps by those who have come to
prefer the life of an economic invalid and prefer to be waited on and
supported by others. And it may safely be predicted that the
good-natured, forgiving and forgetting public will never let even such
undergo sufferings comparable to those now endured by the underpaid
but frantically industrious poor.
Recapitulation.
Land values are a social product. They are rightfully public
property, because they are created and maintained by the public. They
should be collected by the public and used to pay the public expenses.
To accomplish this they should be made the sole source of revenue
taxes. Two of the many advantages would be a rational tax system and a
rising respect for true property rights, public and private. The
latter alone might repay us for making the change.
|