A Reponse to the Rothbardian Criticism
of Henry George
Harry Pollard
[Reprinted from The Good Society,
August-September 1981]
From time to time, we have been dealing with Murray Rothbard's
critiques of Henry George's analysis. Rothbard's remarks are
significant because to a large extent they have been accepted as the
given word on the subject of the 'single tax', even though Rothbard
shows clearly that he hasn't so much missed the boat -- as missed the
ocean. Whenever he has taken up the cudgels against Georgist theory,
he has swung mightily at the wrong target.[1]
Landlords and Tenants
To summarise earlier analysis, Rothbard accepts a land ownership
mechanism that rests on the first claimer, even though such a
contention would turn the first generation into landlords, and we who
come after, into tenants. Nevertheless, when the value of land is low,
and the settling is hard, such a crude allocation might be usefully
expedient.
However, with increasing population and its accompanying increase of
land-value, the first-comers and their heirs become joyful
beneficiaries of Mill's 'unearned increment'. Custom, reinforced by
the power of the state,[2] establishes the privilege of levying a
'tax' on the producers.
Ayn Rand's more attractive fantasy of honest and industrious farmers
tending the soil with fierce independence must give way to sober
reality. Most cultivators are renters paying as much as two thirds of
their crop to someone who inherited from the first-comer'.[3]
'Inherit' obscures the truth, for between first tiller and latest
tenant is a sorry tale of, fraud, violence and murder -- with always
an solicitous state ready to traditionalize the crime and confirm the
legal ownership of the swag.
Land does not behave in the market place as do other things. Henry
George recognised this -- not an arduous exercise -- and offered his
elegant solution, characterized by he Austrian School's von Mises as "utterly
incompatible with the preservation of the market economy"! In
counterpoint, George's remarks about Austrian theory included the
words 'grotesque confusions'!
At the other end of the spectrum, Karl Marx, described by George as "the
prince of muddleheads", gloomily warned that 'Progress &
Poverty' was "the capitalists' last ditch".
Contemporary Georgists would contend that without solution to the
land problem, the market economy of the Austrians is not compatible
with individual freedom. Further, they would assert that failure by
defenders of the free market to address themselves to this question is
directly responsible for the worldwide slide into socialism. Virtually
every legislative 'remedy' of the western world is directed to an
effect of the land problem. Of, course they never work.
Privilege -- the Coercive Value
Value can be created in three ways and one of them is coercive. The
most important 'values' are created by production of wealth. They can
also be created by 'obligation'. If I sign a paper obliging myself to
pay you $1,000 in the future, that paper has an exchange value. The
act of accepting the obligation creates value -- but, unlike
production, it does not add to total wealth.
A third way to create value is to establish a privilege, or private
law ('privi' - 'lege'). A privilege benefits one person at the expense
of another. It's a 'one-way-exchange' and is the child of coercion.
The right to take from another without payment is saleable. With a
private law, backed by force, value has been created without the
production of wealth.
Price Measures Progress
One would expect that normal progress in the arts of production would
reduce the amount of exertion 'paid' for things and that prices would
tend continually to reduce. The effort to maintain 'stable prices' is
essentially a political ploy without economic meaning. The price of
goods to the consumer, over the long haul, will decline. Declining
prices are a measure of advance of a civilization.
Once produced and in the hands of the consumers, products tend to
diminish in value as they are used. They wear out. So, prices suffer
two declines -- the downward trend that accompanies progress and, on
transfer to the consumer, the lessening of value that accompanies
normal usage. These trends are stressed because later we will find
exceptions to the 'rule'.
'Price' may conveniently be regarded as the result of two influences.
First, is the effect of alternatives. One may buy one thing, or one
may buy something else. The 'something else' may be another version of
the same good, or it may be something very different, which still
takes the form of an alternative. [4]
Caddies and Chevies
In an imaginary static market, goods relate to each other according
to their cost of production (exertion). Before you scream that this is
'Marxist Labor theory of value', think for a moment. If the
manufacture of a Cadillac costs you twice as much exertion as you
would spend making a Chevrolet, but you can get only 50% more for the
Caddie in the market, how long will you continue to make Caddies?
Presumably, you will transfer to Chevy manufacture and the Caddies
will begin to disappear from the market -- even as the Chevies
increase.
Thus will Chevies and Caddies reach the market in proportion to
demands that will recover their costs of production. In other words,
prices will reflect the differing efforts that must be put into their
manufacture. A market may be viewed as a counter laden with goods
priced according to their cost to the producer.
The Price Mechanism
However, markets are not static, and a second influence makes itself
felt. Although, goods will 'take station' according to their costs,
varying inputs occur as people bring their production for sale.
Changing supply will affect prices, just as the converse is true --
changing prices will stimulate changes in supply.
This process, whereby demand is constantly fed by changing supply, we
call the 'price-mechanism'. If Cadillacs take station in the market
$1,000 above the Chevrolet price, but the price difference opens up to
$1,000, Chevies will become more attractive to some buyers. Fewer
sales of Cadillacs along with increasing sales of Chevies will close
the gap and again the cars will taken station $1,000 apart.
In this fashion, thousands of goods find their 'equilibrium price'
position in the market and the price-mechanism will keep them hovering
around it.
Steaks and the Mona Lisa
At least, this is true of the overwhelming business of the market
which deals with similar and interchangeable goods. It doesn't happen
with a far less significant activity where goods are priced for their
specific, unique, or limited characteristics.
When you buy a steak, you don't buy a particular piece of meat, but
whatever happens to be in the meat department. You may have particular
preferences, such as more fat, or less fat, 1" thick or 1/2"
thick, a pound or 8 oz -- but at the moment of sale, the permutations
are many between what is available and what you will accept.
But, when you shop for Mona Lisa, you cannot pick between
possibilities, nor raise or lower your sights. You have no
alternative. If you want to buy Mona Lisa there is but one and there
will be no more (but see below).
How the Free Market Works
The market value of a general trade good is profoundly affected by
the 'price mechanism' -- the process which opens and closes the supply
spigot. Yet, the price mechanism works properly only when two
conditions are met: when there is no restriction on the production of
alternative goods; and when there is no restriction on movement of the
goods to market -- free production and free trade.
When goods cannot come to market, the action of the price-mechanism
continues, but fails to establish a clearing price (when supply just
satisfies demand). When production is aborted, or when existing
supplies are kept from market, the price-mechanism process still seeks
to force input by raising prices higher.
Thus, when an increasing price fails to produce another Mona Lisa, it
continues to rise apparently with no end to the increase (the word is
'priceless'). The price-mechanism struggles to draw to market the
non-existent alternative, but does no more than provide incentive for
theft and forgery.[5]
Prince Charles' Wineglass and Billy Beer
A market deals with similar things. A buyer may choose between
non-identical alternatives. One may shop for wineglasses and find any
number of acceptable variations.
Not so for the wineglass that was raised by Prince Charles for the
wedding toast. The authentic wineglass that touched his lips achieves
a value outside of normal commerce. There are no similar glasses, nor
are there any identical alternatives. Demand for this special
wineglass cannot attract to market more identical specimens to compete
and thus lower the price. It is one of a kind.
The behavior of such unique specimens has lead to a growth industry
in 'collectibles' which range from a genuinely unique gem to a
somewhat contrived 'uniqueness' (a check signed 'Aaron Burr' -- $115),
and extends to a uniqueness specifically manufactured by issue of
limited editions, special mintings and first covers.
The value of these collectibles is based not on any original beauty,
or artistry but on their rarity. One does not want a well-crafted
chest of drawers, but a bonnet-top highboy, tiger maple, c. 1765
($3,800). One does not want a cold can of Billy beer, but an empty
Rosalie beer can ($10,000).
Collectibles are valuable the 'almost unique', and even the
apparently unique are not subject to the authority of the
price-mechanism.[6] Prices rise as the market labors to draw forth a
competing supply - and fails. Appreciation is the name of the
collectible game.
You might think that such an aberration would dampen the enthusiasm
of those who advocate the free economy. A continual price increase
without restraint surely indicates the 'invisible hand' has lost its
touch. But, not to worry, these constantly appreciating collectibles
are of little importance to the smooth functioning of the economy.
Churchill's Comment
Said Winston Churchill, speaking to this point: "Pictures do not
get in anybody's way. They do not lay a toll on anybody's labour;
enterprise and production at any point; they do not affect any of the
creative processes upon which the material well-being of millions
depends.
"[7]
Churchill was comparing 'collectibles' with than most essential basis
of all production - land. Why the comparison? Because land, like
collectibles, in the market place is not governed by price mechanism
action. And there's the rub, for land 'collection' does not get in
everybody's way.
Just like other things, land takes its station in the market. Unlike
other things, market separation of locations is not related to
production costs. Land requires no production. It was there before we
were -- and it will be there when we are gone.
Land takes station according to its value as aid to production. This
value to production is known as Economic Rent.[8] Simply put, land
renting $2,000 a year may be expected to add $1,000 more to production
than land renting for $1,000.
Community Created Value
Rent is directly related to the activities of the community as a
whole. It is called a 'socially created value' because it is. The
value of a location would exist without the landholder qua landholder,
but not without a surrounding community of individuals. Essentially,
all that a landholder does -- for a price -- is to allow a producer to
use a value provided by others.
It can be seen that a landholder's return is pure privilege. He does
nothing,
as a landholder, for his Rent. Private law, reinforced by
power of the state, ensures continuance of the 'one-way' exchange.
The first influence on land price in the market place is, like other
things, the available alternative. But the alternative is always other
land. There is no similar thing that may be substituted.
The second influence is, of course, the price-mechanism, but in
crippled cast. For those necessary conditions of a free market --
unrestricted production and mobility, are absent from the land market.
Demand for land shown by rising prices, cannot stimulate production of
more land, nor can it draw land in from elsewhere. Market response to
rising prices -- the arrival of fresh supply -- is impossible. The
mechanism that effects a 'clearing price' for other goods waxes
impotent in the land market.
The Ultimate Collectible
If you have noticed that land, divorced from market control, takes on
the familiar aspect of a genuine 'collectible', you are perceptive.
And the resemblance grows.
One doesn't shop for land in general. Just as you always choose a
particular collectible, so do you always specify a location. You must
locate on Main Street, or at the scenic view. You go to the garment
district, or the legal building. You occupy space near the freeway,
bus stop, heavy sewers, high voltage lines, grade school, or church.
You must settle dose to your fellow wholesale jewellers, or in the
vicinity of other stereo stores.
The desire for the specific, the unique and only site parallels the
desire for the specific, the unique and only Tiger Beer can ($10,000).
Except that beer cans, like pictures, don't get in anybody's way.
In common with other 'collectibles', land is not governed by the
price-mechanism, which means its price pushes ever upward.[9] And the
collectible analogy becomes firmer. If six somewhat comparable
residential lots are for sale and one is built upon, the effect on the
others is instructive. With fewer lots available, the remainder
increase their price. The erection of the first building, adds to the
price of the remaining lots. The process repeats until one lot is
left. This will achieve the highest price of all. It is clearly
evident to landholders that the highest price goes to the last one to
sell. So, they don't sell, they 'collect'.
Producer and Non-Producer
The producer cannot be a collector. One can imagine his thoughts as
he faces rising prices for his product. Should he hold back his
production for even higher prices -- those delectable windfalls? Well,
he should be warned. If he holds his production from market, his
regular customers Will not be pleased and he places his future
business in jeopardy.
Storage of his unreleased product can be expensive, both in space and
because it gets in the way of his continuing production, and even
though his in come has been deferred, the wages of his workers cannot
be. He must pay them, or they'll leave. And while he hesitates, his
competition will be busy.
He must go to market. He is charged, not with merely selling his
production, but with maintaining a viable business. Production is less
like a lake than a river whose flow must not be impeded by a dam.
We can compare the markets. When demand raises the price of widgets,
the widget producer rushes to market. In the act of supplying demand,
he cools the price -- the classic market response. Second to market
will get a lower price. Third to market may find prices have fallen
too low. For the producers, the race goes always to the swift.
No such imperative confronts the landholder. Continuing production is
not an issue. Once the land is sold, the landholder is no longer a
landholder. And his land is rising in price. When you have some thing
to sell which, at no cost to you, will be worth more tomorrow, and yet
more the day after, there's little incentive to putting it on the
market.
Further, the act of holding land from the market still more reduces
available supply and heats the price. The person who holds on longest
to land will receive the best return. [10] The land market becomes
more and morre arthritic as potential vendors choose to sit around
trying to be the last to sell.[11]
It is illuminating to examine the behaviour of the wealth-producer
and the landholder. One must rush to market, the other stays away. One
must keep the wheels turning, the other may lounge on the beach. One
must invest and continually risk over the long term, the other eschews
commitment - preferring a 'cash-crop' income. One gets nothing without
exertion, the other gets everything without exertion.
Rothbard's Alibi
A landholder's job is lucrative -- indeed most of the great American
fortunes have been built on real estate speculation. Feeling a need to
provide an alibi for this diversion of wealth from labor and capital,
Rothbard comes up with a most amusing portentousness. He attempts to
ascribe to the landholder the needful task of "allocating land
sites to their most value-productive uses, i.e. to those uses most
desired by the consumers."[12]
How this differs from simply selling to the highest bidder becomes as
tort up us a train of logic as you might meet anywhere. The sale of
land, according to Rothbard, requires certain arcane rituals. The
owner performs the service of "transferring ownership". It "does
not simply exist; it must be served to the user by the owner".
The owner insures "the most productive locations for each use".
The mind boggles at the thought of the landholder waving his tureen
at a prospect, but a query disturbs the boggle. What does a landholder
do for 100% of the price, that any competent realtor would not do
equally well for a 5% commission. Rothbard is appropriately vague on
this point, though he warns darkly of "grave effects" if the
five-percenter got the business.
And Rothbard's Beliefs
It appears that Rothbard actually believes -- in the face of
overwhelming contrary evidence -- that better sites are all used
before producers move to marginal locations. Certainly, this would be
expected in the market, where one generally buys the best bargain
before turning to second best.
But, at risk of tedium it must be stressed that the land market is
not a free market. So, the 'allocation' and use of land-sites is about
as haphazard, inefficient, uneconomic and downright whimsical as you
could conceive. If the land-site market is an example of Rothbard's
free market process, it has failed every test.
It is frustrating that Rothbard is unable to see a problem so
manifest. Our economic difficulties, from California to New York and
from Vietnam to El Salvadore are essentially land provoked. Even so,
the 'fix' provided by the collectivists (of all political persuasions)
is rarely countered by any free market alternative.
Success and
An outstanding exception is Georgist inspired Taiwanese land
reform.[13[ Despite a population density rising above 1,200 people to
the square mile (about twice that of India and 4-1/2 times that China)
the Taiwanese have a net export of food. Given similar incentive, one
might imagine that farms of India, now teetering always on the brink
disaster, becoming the 'bread basket' of South-East Asia -- and even
perhaps a food exporter to the U.S.
Failure for Libertarianism
Rothbard seems to be unaware of the consequences of failure to solve
the land problem. Our progress towards a free society depends on
effective solution, both here and abroad. And we have little time. In
the wings, and occasionally on center stage, await the communists,
ready and willing to attend to any important matter we may neglect.
Against the realities so well understood by the communists,
Libertarians march bravely, but unarmed. They have lost before they
begin. They will not win 'the hearts and minds' of people by
confirming their position as rack-rented peasants.
They will not persuade the poor, who clearly see the extraordinary
consequences of successive industrial revolutions, that poverty is
inevitable.
The argument that hard work and struggle will take them from squalor
to the good life is likely to be greeted by cynical amusement. Hard
but honest toil at the poverty level retains its glamor only in the
wilder imaginings of George Gilder.
Nor will it be easy to explain to the young that land-price explosion
is simply an idiosyncracy of the free market. That they should be
satisfied with a less than remote chance of raising a family in their
own home, or on their own farm.
Confront them with a 'free market' high rent apartment, or some
overpriced farmland, and you'll end up with instant converts to rent
control and crop subsidy. Without George's free market approach to the
land problem, libertarians are lost.
To the demand "Show me", to where will the libertarians
point? To the US? -- where land was free, or very cheap through much
of its history. But, not now. Hong Kong, so beloved of Milton
Friedman? -- the land is leased by the colony to the entrepreneurs.
Switzerland? -- how lucky to be at the crossroads of Europe. (If
you're eager to own land, grab a crossroads.)
The Georgist Community
Arrant nonsense about the state owning or controlling all the land
(that's Rothbard again) in no way describes a Georgist society.
Ownership would not change, title deeds would remain, powers of
acquisition and sale would be the same. Restrictions would be few or
non-existent.
Major changes would be a complete absence of taxes and the presence
of a user charge for every site above the margin. The Danes call this
a 'ground-debt'. Community created value attaches to your ground, so
you pay your 'debt' -- not a bad name.[14]
The burden of a 'user charge' would make land-sites unattractive as
'collectibles'. No longer would they be kept from the producers. Sites
would enter the market as do labor and capital and would be controlled
by the price mechanism. Land would be occupied only as a prelude to
use. The market would 'allocate' them without the expense or
inefficiency of the landholder. They would enter the arena in orderly
fashion the best sites first -- as one might expect from a free
market.
Cities would become compact and attractive, urban sprawl would end,
home-ownership would bloom, intensive and profitable family farming
would be the rule. The wilderness -- because there would be so much of
it -- might develop into a nuisance. Because proper environmental
husbandry is the corollary of unrestricted economic enterprise,
conservation could well become a joke.
This is the Georgist revolution. It is quiet, reasonable,
non-coercive, proven effective and, by releasing the energies of free
individuals, could win the battle against the collectivists.
NOTES
- Principal error is the
Rothbardian assumption that payment of a Rent charge for a
location is a matter of landholder choice -- rather as if one
could occupy a theater seat, then choose to pay, or not to pay,
for the ticket. In every way, George's 'single tax' may be
regarded as a user charge, which must be paid.
- The term 'state' is derived
from 'estate'. The early fief and the modem state have much in
common.
- People who accept the
landholder/peasant relationship often become outraged when
confronted with the widespread practice of 'rack-renting'. They
hold that only 'fair rents' should be charged, thereby exposing
their ignorance of both the real world and the market.
- You may choose between
Cadillac and Toyota, or between Cadillas and bicycle. On the other
hand, you may decide to buy a suit and use your feet.
- Six 'original' versions of the
Mona Lisa have been authenticated!
- Or, apparently not subject;
Billy Carter's beer cans are being offered as rarities for $1,000
apiece. Yet, unbeknowst to the aspiring collectors, there are tens
of thousands of cases of 'Billy Beer' available in the warehouses
of the south.
- General Election speech -
Lancashire, Dec. 1909
- Rent may be defined as the sum
of advantages, less disadvantages, that attach to a location.
Technically, it's the difference in value between a location and
the best land that can be hand for nothing.
- Until the advent of general
economic collapse: Georgist analysis notes the land price bubble
that precedes every industrial depression. The effective limit to
land price increase occurs when production stops because cost of
location becomes too high.
- Nothing is certain and many a
landholder vainly awaits the freeway, sewers, something --
anything! -- to arrive and prove out his claim. But, at issue is
not a potential, actual, or unrealised profit -- but the economic
consequence of holding ripe land from the market.
- For a filler treatment of
'land paralysis', see "Land Speculation and Ecology"
(Paper presented to the Environmental Section AAAS by Harry
Pollard, Henry George School, Tujunga - 1981).
- "Power and Market"
(Institute for Humane Studies - Menlo Park, 1970).
- Sun Yat Sen was strongly
influenced by Henry George. His philosophy arrived in Taiwan with
the Nationalist Generals. The result is a land reform which has
turned loose the energies of people in pursuit of private profit
-- the 'mainspring of human progress'. So, hidden behind the
somewhat wretched political facade of Taiwan, there exists a
solution to the basic problem of Asia, which is survival.
- Nearly 60 years of Danish
land-value taxes has led to more than 96% of the Danish
|