The Free Market of Henry George
Harry Pollard
[Reprinted from Fragments, 1976-79]
HENRY GEORGE'S analysis in Progress and Poverty leads to the
conclusion that a classical free market is not possible until the "land
problem" is solved.
AH sciences begin with assumptions. For George there are two: "Man's
desires are unlimited", and "Man seeks to satisfy his
desires with the least exertion."
Value is what men desire. It is synonymous with "worth" and
describes that which is preferable. As free men seek an increase in
values by cooperation, a market develops. Specialization becomes the
path to greater riches, and so the market soon adopts the
characteristics of a "clearing house -- a place where goods are
routed to their greatest value increase. A network of relationships
grows, with each participant seeking constantly to improve his
position."
This network is controlled by the price-mechanism. This is the market
process whereby production is stimulated by a higher price, even as
consumption is checked; and, conversely, whereby production is checked
by a lower price, even as consumption is stimulated.
George argues that the price-mechanism will provide proper returns to
his (classical) factors of production. The market will fairly
determine the wages of Labor, the interest of Capital, and the rent of
Land. This holds true only when all factors are drawn to market by
price-mechanism pressure. But those who possess Land do not react to
it as do those who "possess" Labor or Capital.
Labor and Capital must watch market prices and react quickly to
change. The highest price goes to the swift, for the very act of
supply lowers the price. Labor cannot hold back for a higher wage or
it faces starvation. Capital with unused machines earns nothing.
Because of the immediacy of market pressure, the market earns its
reputation for efficient allocation.
As civilization advances, products increase, become more varied, and
above all, become cheaper. Cheapness is the measure of progress. But
there's the rub. Though decreasing product prices are evidence of an
advancing society, so also is increasing land rent.
Rent of a location is the sum of its advantages, less the sum of its
disadvantages, over marginal land, i.e., land which can be had for
nothing. As people gather together to produce and trade, their very
actions and presence are measured by increased rent. Increases in
population tend to bring marginal land into use. To obtain future
income, one needs merely to hold such land until needed. So, soon
there is no land which is not held by someone. The landholder adopts a
policy which runs counter to price-mechanism pressure: "Trade
land tomorrow rather than today."
The necessary conditions for an effective market are not being met.
Essential to the price-mechanism is that increased production and
supply follow a price rise. But new land cannot be produced, and what
exists is kept from the market. Price-mechanism fails -- it cannot
turn back the price rise. The price-mechanism, faced by "land-shortage"
and ever rising prices, waxes impotent and disgraced, the butt for
collectivist scorn and the object of distrust even by those who
believe in a free society. The land market becomes a witches' brew.
George follows this scenario to its final act -- a paralyzed economy
leading to a crash and a general collapse of land prices. His solution
is a particularly elegant one, for, by laying upon landholders a
charge equal to their unearned return, he simply makes land responsive
to the price-mechanism.
Once Land is as costly to keep out of production a-, are Labor and
Capital, response to price-mechanism pressure is assured. With all
factors under control, the market may be left alone to do its
superlative job.
History abounds with instances of "failed laisser-faire."
In every case, the failure stemmed not from a free market that was not
adequate, but from a free market that was not truly free.
|