The Glitch in the Price Mechanism
How the Free Market Fails
Harry Pollard
[April 2013]
Personal and Market Value
Henry George gave the name 'personal value' to subjective value. He
went on to note that 'use value', the subject of Adam Smith's famous
query, is actually personal value. George shrewdly noted that 'use
value' refers not to the capacity of something to be useful, but to
its usefulness to you.
Personal value is of interest to the economist only because of its
relationship to market value. Value at the market can be thought of as
objective as it can be seen by many people at the same time. The
market value of a trade good at the point of exchange confirms itself
in the very act of exchange. We are obliged to make use of market
value, for it's the only hard evidence we have.
When, at a particular time and place an exchange takes place two
values define themselves in full view for all to see. These values are
always equal which leads one to conclude there can be no such thing as
an imbalance of trade.
When two traders exchange a book for a chair, each trader values the
thing he gets more than the thing he gives. Otherwise, he wouldn't
trade. How much more he values the thing he gets is unknown. The only
evidence we have is that at that place and time the book and the chair
had the same value.
Market value is clearly visible. Personal value is hidden, perhaps
even from the person who holds it. Yet, in the act of exchange we are
comparing these two. In our minds we have placed a value on the thing
we have. This value we compare with the market offer. Should the
market offer be higher, we are likely to trade. Should our personal
valuation be higher, we forgo the opportunity. Although we can infer
this, the hard evidence is the actual exchange value in the
marketplace.
Trade, along with its implied division of labor, leads the advance of
civilization. This advance may be gauged by the continual decrease in
the cost of products. Producers try to supply the market with higher
quality goods at a lower price, not because they want to but because
they must if they are to sell their goods.
Producers cannot hold back their production for a higher price. As
the act of reaching the market and supplying demand reduces prices,
the first to arrive will get the best price. Tardiness is penalized by
a smaller return. So, in the long run and in the short, the trader who
would succeed must hurry his goods to market. This has earned for the
market a deserved reputation as an excellent provider of goods to
consumers.
Other pressures push production into the market process. Storage
costs, even with minimum maintenance, are a drain on profit.
Furthermore, the producer wants throughput. He wants to get rid of
production so he can produce more. (Time is an element. If the
exchange value will be greater at a later time, immediate distribution
of goods may be delayed. However, this is part of the production
process.)
Capital
Trade goods, and indeed all products still in the productive process
are given the name Capital. Capital must fulfill three requirements.
It must earn enough to compensate the lender if any of the Capital has
been borrowed. In addition, as products move through the productive
process they must earn enough to make keeping them in production
worthwhile. So, as they move toward an eventual sale, their value must
continually increase. If there is no increase there is no point in
continuing production.
Production continues until the product is in the hands of the final
consumer, whereupon it ceases to be Capital. It is now Wealth.
Wealth
Wealth a name given to goods in the hands of the consumer. The
primary characteristic of consumer goods is that, unlike Capital, they
diminish in value as wear and tear take their toll. Consumer goods are
used and are thus subject to physical depreciation. Economists are
inclined to allow size and longevity to influence definition. Thus, a
home, as a durable good, is given false status as Capital when it can
be better likened without prefix to a suit of clothes, or your lunch
or any other consumable.
Breaking like things out of their conceptual category is not helpful
to scientific reasoning, even though it can usefully pad a curriculum.
With maintenance, a house may last for many decades. With patching and
other care, a suit may last for several years. Cryogenically or
chemically, food may outlast both. But, common to them all will be a
depreciating value, the result of cheaper replacements, rising
maintenance costs and the inevitable onset of obsolescence.
Collectibles
To the simple division of products between Capital which earns, and
Wealth which is consumed must be added a third category of goods. This
is a kind of consumable Wealth which appreciates in value. The class
is called Collectibles.
Why people initially collect is a matter for the psychologists to
ponder. Certainly age is a factor. Perhaps because our first need is
to survive, advanced age is attractive. If you are old, you've made
it. Our reverence for age transfers to old things, living and dead.
So, elephants, whales, sequoias, stately homes, antiques, even early
comic books become desirable simply because they have been around for
a long while. People collect things which are old because they are
old. This demand for old things is reflected in their higher market
value. Soon, these things are collected because they have an
increasing market value.
The person with a collectible is always looking ahead to an
anticipated future value. If a similar item has been sold for $10,000,
he won't regard his collectible as being worth this this amount, but
rather as what is likely to be worth in the future.
Also, unlike Wealth which loses value over time, the collector
endeavors to prevent anything that might diminish the value of his
collectible Wealth. Rather than allow the children to do their
homework on his 16th century antique desk, he wraps it up in plastic
and puts it in the corner of the bedroom.
The Price Mechanism
At this point, we must reexamine the market price mechanism. This is
the most endlessly pawed over segment of economic theory.
The argument usually divides along political lines, with one side
praising the market as the best method for 'allocating scarce
resources', even as the other side points to its imperfections and
outright failures. Both sides are somewhat right as will become
evident by reminding ourselves of the actual process of the price
mechanism. When prices rise, goods come to market and reduce prices.
That, along with its reverse, is all there is to it. However, the
assumption is made that, in response to a price increase, goods can be
produced and brought to market. This may not be the case. In fact, we
can say that when replacement goods either cannot be produced, or
cannot reach the market, the price mechanism fails. This condition may
arise from coercive political action, non-coercive market decision, or
non-coercive natural monopoly.
Whichever is responsible, when demand asserts itself and prices
increase, goods do not reach the market. Unsatisfied demand presses
price upward seeking to draw fresh supply and fails. It does not
escape the attention of the owners of such goods that price today is
greater than price yesterday and, with fresh supplies unavailable, the
prospect for tomorrow looks even better. It is better to wait than to
sell. Unique goods achieve a value based not on their utility, or
their intrinsic worth, but on their unique ability to subvert the
price mechanism and appreciate as they are held. So, a Rosalie Beer
can may achieve an exchange value of $10,000 for no better reason than
it is the only one of its kind and may therefore be considered a valid
collectible. This is a noncoercive natural monopoly. A limited print
edition, or first cover, or 'we broke the mold', contrive collectibles
by market decision. Import bans, or patent restrictions may create
high prices by coercion, but do not always necessarily 'collectibles'.
Collectibles
A collectible is a consumable that offers greater benefit from
collection than use.
Collectibles stay away from the market, for tomorrow the price may be
higher. Non-collectibles must face multiple attacks on their value if
they delay sale. They must rush to market for tomorrow may be too
late. In the case of the non-collectible, the first to get to market
gets the highest price; in the case of the collectible, the last to
market gets the highest price. If the collectible phenomenon adversely
affected us, the activity might provoke our concentrated attention,
but as Winston Churchill said in addressing the collectible question,
'Paintings don't get in anybody's way'. We dont worry much about
the collectible market. However, a vital part of the economic system,
a part crucial to all production acts like a collectible.
Location
This is Land, which in classical political economy named the concept
of natural resources untouched by Man. The term Land covers many
things, but common to them all is location.
Location is perhaps the single characteristic of land that, in these
days of atomic fission fits the description provided by John Stuart
Mill 'the original and indestructible power of the soil'. And
locations can be 'collected'. In every way, location fulfills the
conditions of collectability. The number of locations is fixed, no
more can be produced. Each is unique and obviously cannot be moved.
The price mechanism cannot draw new locations to the market in
response to price increase, yet will try by pressing prices ever
higher. It becomes obvious that location prices (albeit with an
occasional stutter) move always upward. The usefulness of a location
in production becomes secondary to its value as a collectible, so
locations are kept from the market.
Unlike the free market where everyone is trying to the market first
to take advantage of a rising price, in the collectible land market
people are trying to be the last to sell.
When an economic factor essential to human existence is disciplined
by a market where everyone is trying to be the last to sell, the
economy has a problem. Given this situation, land sales become less a
reaction to market pressure, than to outside circumstances. A death in
the family, a cash flow shortage, a pressing tax demand, any may serve
to place land on the market. And when sold, land is likely to fall
into the hands of another collector.
Future Anticipated Value
We recall that trade takes place when market value is seen to be
greater than personal value.
When your personal valuation of something is $1,000, but the market
is offering $2,000, you are likely to trade. When your personal
assessment is $2,000, but the market offers $1,000, you are unlikely
to trade. As a collector, you are concerned, not with present market
value, but with the future anticipated value of the collectible. If
you did not believe that this future value would be higher, you
wouldn't collect. Thus, your personal valuation of the collectible is
the future value which you anticipate will be greater than present
market. So, ceteris paribus you do not sell. But, this is not the end
of the story. When pent up demand is such that a location similar to
your own sells at your anticipated future value, this new sale price
becomes present market value. Your response will be to adopt a new
personal value based on yet higher anticipations a standard
collectible response.
As a result, the land market suffers a paralysis that casts a shadow
over all productivity. Government compulsory purchase is used to
attack the problem, but it is an expediency that merely compounds the
problem, for nothing raises anticipations more than the prospect of a
governmental bottomless purse intervening in the market. Breaking the
land price barrier by force simply raises higher the future barriers
to production.
Price mechanism failure in the land market spills over into every
other market with which land is intimately connected. When apartment
rents rise in response to demand, apartment construction should gain
pace until, with demand met, rents should fall. Even high in situ
costs are no longer a factor, for factory manufactured housing can be
produced both speedily and cheaply. (Factory produced module housing
can be manufactured and erected on site for a total of 50 man hours.)
But, apartments need a site on which to perch, and sites cannot be
factory made and trucked to market. So, even though both factory and
traditionally constructed apartment costs exhibit continuing decline,
they are not built and apartment rents continue to rise. Rent control
does nothing to address the problem of site 'collection'. It has
political manifestations as landholders and government indulge in
newsworthy thrusts and parries. But, it exacerbates rental housing
shortages, does little to help the poor, the supposed beneficiaries of
the exercise, and creates, in random fashion, both privileged and
underprivileged classes.
Slump
There have been more theories of the business cycle than there have
been business cycles. Most of them suggest hauling an economy up from
slump by stimulating demand.
Almost forgotten is the truism that before consumption there must be
production. Full warehouses at the bottom of the depression indicates
that the problem is lack of consumption. The question that is never
asked, yet is equally obvious is How do people consume?
The answer is, of course, by producing first. If they are unable to
produce, they will have nothing to consume whether they produce for
themselves or for trade. The right of a consumer to demand is a
function of his ability to produce. When land is 'collected' the price
of sites climbs ever higher. Production, which cannot take place
without land, is forced to pay a speculative premium which continually
becomes more exacting.
Eventually, Labor and Capital cannot pay the tab, and production
slows and stops. Industries most closely linked to the land, such as
farming and construction, are usually the first to collapse, but
others are not far behind. To some degree this is recognized by the
huge governmental assistance at all levels to these basic industries.
Yet, all these subsidies do is pay an existing personal value of
landholders and stimulate increases in the personal values of other
landholders.
Governmental compulsory purchase appears to be the only choice if
downtowns are to be revived. Yet, each time the problem is solved
this way, it simply raises the barrier of rising personal expectation
around their downtown. These are tomorrow's slums - problems that
arise from a false solution.
Ending Land Collection
It should be understood that these acts of land speculation is not a
crime. Site collectors' can hardly be blamed for acting like normal
human beings, within the law and according to common practice.
However, if the process is harmful in general to the economy, and in
particular to each individual who wishes to rent, to buy, or to build
a home or factory the community is obliged to protect itself.
Effectively to deal with this problem, we must return 'location' to
the discipline of the market price mechanism. By far the most
promising direction to take would be the introduction of community
rent charges for land use. As urban site value measures the positive
advantages of community activity, it would seem both just and
equitable to levy a charge for this benefit on each site holder
whether or not he chooses to take advantage of the benefit.
The economic consequences of such a charge would be to push unused
and underused sites onto the market. Many economic difficulties erupt
out of our natural propensity to collect sites for future gain. If the
prospect of future gain was removed even as present holding without
use became unprofitable, sites would be released to the market. Prices
would tumble, the market would resume control, and a variety of
apparently insoluble economic problems would disappear.
|