My Critique of Modern "Georgism"
Harry Pollard
[A series of exchanges on issues relating to political economy,
extending over a period of months during 2014 / Part 2 of 2]
HARRY POLLARD
The following exchange took place between Mason Gaffney and myself
with regard to Skepticism 4.
I said: I remember dividing us between Georgists and land-value
taxers way back in the 1950's in Canada, but at that time I didn't
realize its eventual significance (as I see it).
MASON GAFFNEY
Neither did I, nor do I now. You were going to show that modern
Georgists (like me, I guess) were pushing to tax wages in the guise of
a lvt, but I've seen no more about that. So what's this all about now?
HP: I didn't say or imply there was any "pushing to
tax wages in the guise of a LVT". What I said was that present
efforts to tax land values are likely to tax only some of the
contract rent. Rack-rent would remain, along with its consequences,
but some of it would be collected by the tax man.
I pointed out that urban economic rent was the result of the
presence and access of the surrounding community. That it was a
value that attaches to a land location and was a measure of the
advantage given to the location by the community. If labor pays this
value to a landholder (or to the community) he loses nothing from
his wages. He pays (say) $100 a week for the right to work there: he
gets $100 worth of advantage from the location.
This assumes that advantage is measured in a free market. The free
market is highly efficient in relating supply and demand. As the
community changes in various ways, perhaps increasing in size and
well-being, or moving to different parts of the city, so will the
free market accurately note the changes. I would think that
land-value assessors would have all city locations in their
computers and would continually bring them up to date.
The present land location market is not free. For a free market to
operate at its optimum efficiency two conditions are necessary.
There must be no restriction on production, and no restriction on
movement to market.
We cannot increase the number of locations in a city and we cannot
move more locations in from outside. The free market does not
control location values.
We must have a land location to live. We need a location to work
on, to live on, just to have somewhere to stand. Demand is a given.
Supply is another matter. I went into the psychology of a
landholder in an earlier "Skepticism". Suffice it to say
that he is likely to be reluctant to supply. When supply is short,
the price mechanism raises prices. So long as the shortfall
continues prices will move up. This extra amount that labor pays has
to come from somewhere and it comes from his wages.
This is not economic rent that is being paid, but contract rent
(something paid by one to another). (Fred calls it contractual.)
Contract rent will increase until it becomes rack-rent, which is
defined by me as the highest amount that can be paid while
maintaining production. Any higher demand will cause production to
stop.
Henry George, less of a panty-waist then me, said grimly, any
further exaction would lead to "a cessation of life".
This "syphoning" of wages into rack-rent permeates the
whole economy and is the reason why "the poor will always be
with us". Economists, politicians, and fair-minded folk promote
welfare of various kinds to help the poor. Though the incomes of
poor may be raised, inevitably rack-rents remove the benefit. This
is why last year's welfare doesn't appear to work this year.
When modern land-value taxers press their case they are essentially
asking for some collection of rent. Yet all their land-value tax
will do is to skim off some of the rack-rent. As rack-rent is taken
from wages, a land-value tax that bites into rack-rent is taxing
wages at secondhand.
After the land-value tax, the poor will still be with us, but then
haven't they always been?
The land-value tax can work if it's high enough. I won't go into
the mechanics of this is its little more complicated than we often
assume. Enough must be collected to induce the general unloading of
vacant and underused land. The result should be that rack-rent
induced land prices will topple and land location prices will return
to control of a free market. (To achieve the goal of justice all the
economic rent must be collected.)
Once rack rent is gone Labor will be back to paying economic rent
and the present heavy weight on production will end. We have become
so used to this burden that we no longer think about it. For
example, why does it take us 30 years of debt to buy a house? I've
seen factory made start-up housing priced at not much more than the
good car. Yet we are conditioned into believing that to buy a house
takes most of our working life.
One might argue that if we can get a little LVT that will lead to
greater things. The problem with doing things gradually is that each
step becomes progressively harder as opposition grows. A victory for
a small collection of rack-rent may be as far as you get and,
remember, that is simply taxing wages!
HARRY POLLARD
Continuing the discussion of the vital difference between economic
rent and rack-rent.
DAVID GIESEN
Am I missing something? My understanding of George's intent--it's
certainly mine-- is to tax away the potential rent of a location, both
rent actual and speculative. So, along with Mason I ask, "So
what's this all about?" Are there folks out there asking for any
less?
HP: We just want the "rent actual". I don't
know of any land-value taxers who are advocating the full collection
of economic rent - a necessary condition for a Georgist economy.
While they do push the advantages of the land-value tax such as that
is not a weight on production as are other taxes, they mostly seem
to echo Milton Friedman's comment that it is "the least bad tax".
Much of their attention seemed directed to the amount that could be
collected, with totals that seem to verge on the fantastic. This
because they are based on rack-rents that would disappear with a
full collection of economic rent.
The greatest successes in the US are in Pennsylvania with some 22
cities have some degree of land-value taxation. Perhaps the best
prospect is in Clairton where their land-value tax finances
education as well as their Council activities. If we had proper
organization, Henry George classes should have been set up in
Clairton to start producing local Georgists who understand the
importance of full collection.
DAN SULLIVAN
You are wrong. Incremental shifts to LVT have led to lower rents in
the municipalities of Australia and Pennsylvania. There are no rack
rents like California rack rents and those are the direct result of
curtailing real estate taxes.
In 1911, Pittsburgh had the second-highest rents in the nation (after
New York City). As it introduced gradual increases in land value tax
from 1913-1925, we had increased construction with flat real estate
prices while the rest of the country was seeing increased real estate
prices with flat construction. By 1960, we were the most affordable of
the 100 largest cities. Pittsburgh lost its LVT in 2000, and rents are
rapidly increasing.
HP: I think you were pretty much alone, Dan, in keeping
Pittsburgh sensible. A fine example of what can be done by a
dedicated individual. It was sheer stupidity mixed with quite a bit
of chicanery that threw out the land-value tax and replaced it with
other taxes and, among other things, expensive subsidies to
construction. Without doubt, a land-value tax produces better
results than any of its competitors. It really is the least bad tax.
Yet, to be Georgist, the collection of rent must be enough to make
speculative land a burden - enough of a burden to cause land to be
unloaded onto the market. Then, prices will drop until they reflect
economic rent.
I taught classes in Pittsburgh in the early 60s and I recall large
occupied buildings in the downtown area. That would never happen
with a full collection of economic rent.
An argument can be made that we have to make a start. That we have
to collect some rent so later we can collect much more. I think this
is unlikely to happen - except perhaps in Clairton. (Maybe Josh can
give us more information on what is happening there.)
In any event, present attempts to tax land values appear mostly to
take some of the rack-rent. An advantage is that it does teach local
politicians that it can be done.
FRED FOLDVARY
Thanks, Harry, I agree.
However, in my analysis, as the rate of LVT rises, rack rent will
fall, until when LVT is 100% of economic rent, and then rack rent
disappears. The greater the collection of rent, the greater the
carrying cost of underused land.
Mason made the good point that an explicit cost in money has a
greater punch than the implicit cost of not getting maximum revenue
from rentals.
HP: Quite right, Fred! And as is usual, Mason is right.
Land-value taxes will bite into rack rent (as would other taxes and
other privileges). Important is that the rent collection must be
high enough to cause unloading of speculative land. The unloading
will begin long before we reach 100%. Probably the first to respond
to serious economic rent collection would be large land investment
firms that could see the writing on the wall. They will begin to
sell and invest elsewhere. Land prices will fall. This will induce
small speculators (or as they are called nowadays property
investors) somewhat reluctantly to unload. As land prices fall
further (as a result of the unloading) they will begin more closely
to reflect economic rent rather than rack-rent.
BRET BARKER
In other words, Georgism is dead without a radical dose of
collection. (We cannot get to the meat unless we cut lots of fat
away.) LVT will not take away the general tradition of getting to
'profit' from land ownership. It must make landholders as landholders
queasy.
ALANNA HARTZOK
By any other name, still the same - the land problem must be solved.
HP: Amen!
HARRY POLLARD
My last E-Mail had a reply to Dan Sullivan referring to large
occupied buildings in Pittsburgh.
That should have been "unoccupied".
Sorry about that!
I've been asked, are Georgists Left or Right?
I had a radio program some years ago titled "From the Radical
Center". I would say we are neither Left nor Right but in the
center, but we are also radical - in the sense of applying ourselves
to the root of problems.
I oppose the planned economy because it is inefficient and ultimately
a failure. Note the condition of semi-planned economies around the
world. On the other hand, I would say the "free market" does
what the left says it will - send wages to ever lower levels with the
bottom tier at subsistence.
The free market is by far the best way to run an economy - but the
land problem must first be solved. With an unsolved land problem, the
free market fails. This is why "free marketers", when they
take power, inevitably lose it again as their economy fails to help
labor.
I should stress that though the privilege of taking rack-rent is the
fundamental privilege, both Left and Right governments harbor many
more privileges.
(Defined as a 'private law' designed to help some at a cost to
others.) It is important to convince reformers of all stripes that the
spoils of privilege should not be taxed as is offered everywhere as
the way to deal with inequality.
Rather, privileges should be abolished - all of them. Get rid of them
all,
As I said, Georgists are radicals and not, as George Wallace might
have said, pusseyfooting reformers!
I hope our friends in the north-east are surviving the weather.
HARRY POLLARD
Here are a number of replies from top Georgists on the important
subject of definitions, the basic language of economics. Henry George
managed with seven definitions of basic terms and two assumptions.
I began my critique of our basics with very careful definitions of
this terminology.
Perhaps Mase didn't see the early emails.
MASON GAFFNEY
This dialogue might lead somewhere if you would define your terms,
especially rent, rackrent, speculation. Otherwise . well, here we are,
nowhere.
HP: Bret Barker answered but not completely to Mason's
satisfaction who replied:
MASON GAFFNEY
Defining terms is not to make things harder, but easier.
Thanks for trying. A good start, but note that you use the undefined
term "speculation" to help define "ec rent" - and
that's just one of many problems.
BRET BARKER
Is this better?
Rack Rent: The value that attaches to available locations under
modern conditions where much land is held from use for future gain or
set aside by government restrictions on use.
Economic Rent: The value that would attach to locations if there were
no profit in merely holding valuable land off the market for future
gain and unreasonable government restrictions on the use of land were
eliminated.
My understanding of Henry George is that he aimed to reduce this Rack
Rent to Economic Rent by increasing the annual rate of taxation on
assessed values until the profit of merely holding land for future
gain was eliminated. The goal was to increase economic opportunity for
all with good wages. With Rack Rent eliminated, a continuous fund of
Economic Rent would replace taxes on Labor or Capital.
I left out 'speculation,' but included the holding of land for future
gain.
ALANNA HARTZOK
Bret - this is nice and clear, yes precisely, ha ha.
HARRY POLLARD
Dan Sullivan doesn't like my use of the word rack-rent.
DAN SULLIVAN
The Oxford English Dictionary defined rack rent as the full market
rent, as opposed to the nominal rent that Irish lords had charged.
However, this full market rent existed in the context of vast tracts
of land being held out of use through enclosure. I therefore define
rack-rent as an artificially high rent produced by land being held
back from the market. Natural rent would then be the rent no rent
could be held off the market rent-free. This is very similar to
Brett's definition below.
In any case, the common usage of the term "rack rent"
implies some kind of mechanism for gouging the renter.
HP: The Oxford English Dictionary does not determine how
we use words. It reflects common usage, which accounts for some very
peculiar words in its pages in modern times. I defined rack-rent as
the highest contract rent that can be demanded from a tenant while
maintaining production. I also noted Henry George's use of this
highest contract rent as any higher would mean a "cessation of
life".
Frank Chodorov had something to say about this. This was submitted
by Bret Barker. You'll note the "permission to live"
price.
FRANK CHODOROV
"The beneficiaries of state power are the privileged classes.
The greatest privilege which the state can confer is that of
collecting rent from users of the earth. As all production consists of
the application of labor to land, the owners of mines, franchises, and
other choice spots are in a position to demand a permission-to-live
price."
HP: "Highest possible contract rent"- "cessation
of life"- "permission to live" seem to be within the
meaning of rack-rent as it was originally used.
MASON GAFFNEY
Dan: The Oxford English Dictionary defined rack rent as the full
market rent, as opposed to the nominal rent that Irish lords had
charged.
DS: Mason: That is, of course, the opposite of Harry's
usage.
Dan: However, this full market rent existed in the context of vast
tracts of land being held out of use through enclosure.
DS: Mason: Land is always being held out of "full"
use, in varying degrees. Ted Turner recently held about a million
acres, "because he likes to look at it". Where is the line
between partial use and full use?
Dan: I therefore define rack-rent as an artificially high rent
produced by land being held back from the market. Natural rent would
then be the rent where no rent could be held off the market rent-free.
DS: Mason: and last sentence does not parse. Is that what
you really mean?
Dan: This is very similar to Brett's definition.
In any case, the common usage of the term "rack rent"
implies some kind of mechanism for gouging the renter.
DS: Mason:"Implies", yes, but that is a
connotation, not a denotation. One might also say it this way: "rack
rent" is a political pejorative used to stir up a mob (justly
or not). You cannot build a science on such unclear and tendentious
meanings.
HARRY POLLARD
I think my definition of rack-rent is perfectly clear I said
rack-rent was the highest contract rent that can be demanded from a
tenant while maintaining production
FRED FOLDVARY
Economic Rent: The value that would attach to locations if there
were no profit in merely holding valuable land off the market for
future gain and unreasonable government restrictions on the use of
land were eliminated.
"Economic rent" is a standard term in economics.
The standard meaning of economic rent is income beyond what is needed
to provide a factor in its most productive use.
Since land has no cost of production, by this meaning, all land rent
is economic rent. No rent needs to be kept by the title holder in
order to provide land.
I think it's best to use standard definitions, whenever possible.
If we want a term for the land rent that would exist with full LVT, I
have in a couple of articles used "geo-rent".
HP: The problem with the standard meaning, Fred, is that
it applies to all factors. We must either explain our particular use
of economic rent (we shouldn't have to), or use another term, as you
suggest.
Then Mason chided us for making it seem too easy and he proceeded
to make it hard!
MASON GAFFNEY
"rent" is an annualized (or smoothed or levelized) figure,
while actual net returns to land come in the form of irregular pulses
of costs and revenues.
To levelize these pulses one must first discount them all to the
present, making them commensurable. Then when you have made them
commensurable you can sum them. Then levelize this sum of present
values to its annual equivalent.
Those are mathematical operations requiring you to:
- forecast all costs and revenues into the infinite future, which
no one knows enough to do, and which individuals will do
differently and subjectively.
- Use an interest rate for discounting. Relevant interest rates
differ widely among individuals' and groups of them (like
corporations and governments) because lenders do not allocate
credit by marginal productivity, but by collateral security.
- Also use an interest rate to levelize the present value to its
annual equivalent, which is land rent.
- In a rising market your levelized land rent > rent derived
from the current use alone. You must decide which of those
meanings of "rent" you mean.
Generally in this thread so far, writers have apparently assumed
there is a smooth and easy equivalence between the net return from the
current use and the market value of land, overlooking the important
fact that the latter derives from an infinite series of future uses,
mostly more lucrative than the extant use.
DAN SULLIVAN
I made no such assumptions. I was thinking of rent in terms of what a
user would pay this year or for the length of a lease. Price is indeed
a speculative projection of future rents, and, to a lesser degree, so
is a long-term lease. The variables that have to be considered in
estimating price are important, but do not factor into the definition
of rent, economic rent, natural rent or rack rent.
I believe the original intent was how to distinguish rack rent from
the natural rent that would exist under a substantial land value tax.
HP: That was indeed the original intent, Dan.
With regard to Mason's analysis of economic rent, it seems to me to
be unnecessarily complicated. In a Georgist society a Georgist
assessor will use the equivalent of comparable sales among other
things.
Urban rents relate to each other. I believe the Danes first used
'street valuations', but I think now it is quite common. In other
words, the whole street except the corners have the same valuation.
I have even seen on Danish land-value maps entire subdivisions with
the same valuation. If sites are changing hands at a premium above
the "official" valuation, changes are made in the
Assessor's computer.
I fear the process of practically finding economic rent must be
left in the hands of the assessor rather than the economist.
And it should not be difficult.
HARRY POLLARD
Mase and I have been friends for almost 50 years though, at times,
he's thrown up his hands at some of my antics. He is an economist of
amazing scholarship. Not many could in a couple of E-Mails casually
toss off a quote from early 19th century William Blake's "Jerusalem"
and early 20th century Karel Capek's RUR (Rossum's Universal Roberts).
Capek was the inventor of the term Robot.
So, it is with great pleasure for me to take issue with two of his
submissions to the definitions discussion.
MASON GAFFNEY
The rent I could get "this year" for my obsolescent, aged,
and depreciated avocado grove is about zero. The price I am asking is
what our broker recommends based on sales of "comparables"
nearby for residential use, which is a lot higher. The same is true in
zones of transition from lower to higher uses over vast areas of the
U.S.A. and the world. Current annual rent is a fiction, and to derive
land price by "capitalizing" "what a user would pay
this year" is accordingly fictional.
HP: The economic rent, or natural rent, of your avocado
grove is probably about the same as that of other land in the
immediate area. The land component of the "comparables"
price you are asking is based on contractual rent which is probably
rack-rent.
Whatever improvement is on a particular location does not affect
the economic rent of that location. So your avocadoes will have no
effect on the Rent of your grove.
Real estate agents along with property assessors use contractual
rent or the price derived from it, though this is not straight
capitalization but rather more than that for reasons I have
mentioned in previous emails. Land being held from use assumes all
the characteristics of a collectible, of which the most obvious is
that the collector's valuation is of the future anticipated value of
the collectible.
To this must be added the peculiar nature of land-holding. There is
a certain cachet to being a land-holder that sets him apart from the
common people in business or production. Once the land is sold he is
no different from them, so why should he sell? Then, in an economy
that is improving steadily, his land-value is likely to keep pace
and as it rises so does his price.
Also, a favorable tax system doesn't hurt!
Meantime, professional land speculators who, you'll recall, are now
dubbed "property investors", hold land from use to collect
the natural increase in land-value that accompanies an improving
economy.
It should be understood that speculation is not bad. It is an
important and necessary part of the free market. It helps to flatten
out valleys and peaks. But, because of the monopoly aspects of land,
speculative land prices soar.
You know my favorite example in the UK.
- The 13 hectare (32 acres) Battersea Power Station became
derelict in 1982.
- It was purchased by John Broome for £1.5 million pounds
in 1987.
- A "developer" bought it from him for £10
million in 1993.
- Nothing was to it until the end of 2006 when it was sold for £400
million.
Incidentally, I don't use speculator in a pejorative sense. As
Churchill might say, the speculator is simply doing what is legal
and according to common usage.
I just want to remove land speculation from the economy, perhaps
the most important reason for the full collection of economic rent.
MASON GAFFNEY
To write that other variables "do not factor into the definition
of rent" is to overlook the arbitrary nature of definitions. "THE"
definition of rent is a nonesuch. I recommend an old comic story by
Ellis Parker Butler, "Pigs is pigs". Or any readable book on
semantics - I like Stuart Chase, The Tyranny of Words. There is no
word-God up there who decrees what words mean. Any word just "means
to you what it means to you".
HP: Henry George went to great lengths to ensure that
basic economic terms would "mean the same to all of us".
Without agreement of the meaning of the words we use, we cannot
sensibly talk to each other.
Then comes usage, but, as you know, the subverters of economic
thought have succeeded all too well in jumbling usage in economic
discourse, leaving us with a Tower of Babel.
I would not recommend taking a term used in Ireland in the 19th
Century to describe or analyze conditions today and elsewhere. For one
thing, Irish peasants growing potatoes put in few durable buildings or
other such improvements. Today, in Wisconsin, to put in a dairy means
building a barn, and the owner's house, and other outbuildings. So in
Year #1 there is a huge negative rent, to be followed by several years
of positive rents. Which of those years would you choose to measure "the"
land rent? You have to take whole cycles and annualize them.
HP: The London Times sent an able man to Ireland to
investigate the living conditions of the rack-rented Irish before
the famine. He was by no means anti-landlord yet his description of
the condition of the people was devastating. Families lived in huts
with muddy floors on a diet almost entirely of potatoes. The husband
would eat 10 pounds a day, the rest of the family lesser amounts.
When the potato crop failed, staying alive was difficult or
impossible. One horrible thing I remember from his report concern
the workhouses. They had a wooden wall that swung open. When
somebody died - which was often - they would simply open the flap
and push the corpse outside. The landlords were very rarely in
Ireland. They were at the Court of St. James while a manager ran
their estates, some of which were as large as counties.
Well, of course that sort of thing doesn't happen now. We give
welfare to the poor. Imagine what would happen if there were no
welfare. I suspect that those at the bottom of the wage pyramid
would barely survive - or not survive. Rack-rent exacts everything
possible from labor. The sooner we can do away with it the better.
With regard to your Wisconsin dairy farmer, in Year #1 the economic
rent wouldn't change, nor would it change in succeeding years -
except for outside influences.
MASON GAFFNEY (answering Bret Barker)
Every landholding is "speculative" because land lasts
forever, and we cannot know the far future (or even the near future
very well, but the farther future you look, the fuzzier is your view).
- Even to forecast no change is speculative
- Thus, almost every landowner is a speculator. It you just want
shelter, you rent.
HP: In this case, our lives are "speculative"
for we cannot know the future. Why restrict this to landholding?
Today, the most common usage of "speculator" as a
pejorative is for a person who buys underused land with a view to
putting it to a higher use, or a more intensive use. The opposite of
H.G.'s usage.
HP: I rather think that putting land to a higher use is
not the function of the speculator but the intention of the
developer who buys it from the speculator. Here is something via Wyn
Achenbaum.
WYN ACHENBAUM
Charles Village: One man won't sell his rental property to a
developer who needs the block.
By Scott Calvert
Sun Staff - Originally published August 19, 2004
C. William Struever is one of Baltimore's shrewdest, most successful
developers. Daniel F. Jackson Jr. is a Pasadena man who owns a handful
of rental properties.
Who has more pull? In this case, it isn't Struever.
That's because Jackson owns a Charles Village rowhouse needed by
Struever to develop a key part of the $150 million College Town dorms,
shops and condominiums in North Baltimore near the Johns Hopkins
University.
But Jackson - unlike others who have made big profits by selling
nearly identical rowhouses to Struever for up to $400,000 - has
declined to sell, and nobody can make him.
Critics say he is greedy to seek a reported $1.5 million on a block
where houses went for $100,000 just four years ago. Jackson insists he
wants only a "decent" deal and is unmoved by pleas to sell
in time for a planned October groundbreaking.
HP: Who is the speculator and who is the developer?
MASON GAFFNEY
Note that taxing land does not always or necessarily suppress wild
speculative behavior. Thus in the boom of the 1920s there was a rash
of special improvement districts around growing cities. These
districts had tax powers over land. They borrowed megabucks for street
improvements, including water supplies and drains. These bonds were
secured by their power to tax lands. They overshot the mark and the
bubble burst, giving local improvement bonds a bad name for years.
Chicago, Detroit, most of NY State and Florida, were heavily involved,
along with parts of California.
HP: This is why I point out that some land-value tax
doesn't accomplish what we want. It will have some good effects as
noted by Dan in Pittsburgh, but it will not end speculation. It is
necessary to collect the full economic rent of land, or at least
enough to force landholders to abandon their vacant and underused
land.
Drastic? Tell that to the 160,000 homeless people in Los Angeles.
HARRY POLLARD
I was a little hard on Mason and he replied appropriately with the
theme from "Looney Toons" (I told you he was an economist of
amazing scholarship!) However, I will continue to ask awkward
questions about our certainties.
I believe that Henry George created a genuine School of Classical
Political Economy. He treated it as a science -something modern
neoclassicals have failed to do, though they have a dozen different
amd conflicting "sciences".
As Mase said "the subverters of economic thought have succeeded
all too well in jumbling usage in economic discourse, leaving us with
a Tower of Babel."
After his excellent analysis, he perhaps made a mistake in coming up
with a simple solution to the problem he uncovered. This took over and
the policy of taxing land values overwhelmed the more profound aspects
of his thinking.
This is the situation now where most land-value taxers appear to
concentrate on what Milton Friedman called "the least bad tax".
Yet, George was not advocating a "least bad tax". His target
was extreme and lasting poverty and involuntary unemployment.He began
"Progress and Poverty" by pointing to the incredible
increase in the power to produce and asking why then is it so hard to
make a living?
If only modern neo-classical economists would stop meddling with the
money and concentrate on answering that question after taking a good
look at George's thinking.
MASON GAFFNEY
Oh, the merry-go-round broke down
As we went 'round and 'round
Each time 'twould miss we'd steal a kiss
While the merry-go-round went
Um-pah-pah, um-pah-pah
Um-pah, um-pah, um-pah-pah
Oh, the merry-go-round broke down
It made the darndest sound
The lights went low, we both said "Oh"
And the merry-go-round went
Um-pah-pah, um-pah-pah
Um-pah, um-pah, um-pah-pah
Oh, what fun, a wonderful time
Finding love for only a dime
Oh, the merry-go-round broke down
But you don't see me frown
Ev'rything is fine and now she's mine
'Cause the merry-go-round went
Um-pah-pah, um-pah-pah
Um-pah, um-pah, um-pah-pah
Oh, the merry-go-round broke down
HP: "Th-th-that's all, folks!" (But it isn't!)
HARRY POLLARD (writing to Ed Dodson)
As you know, I don't regard the sales price of land as a simple
capitalization of rack-rent. Rather, in addition to capitalization are
other influences. I mentioned the peculiar cachet that attaches to a
landowner. While the producer wants throughput to keep refilling his
empty shelves, once the landowner sells, that's it. He has money but
he has lost his station in the community.
Then there is the simple fact that in a growing economy the value of
his land is going to keep increasing so why should he sell and invest
when he has a "capital gains" income taxed at a lower rate?
I put quotes around capital gains because capital doesn't gain. It
depreciates with use - it wears out. Or, at least, Georgist capital
does. The neoclassicals have messed up the concept of capital. In any
event, the capital gains tax actually taxes land so we'll will keep
that quiet.
Finally, land is treated as a collectible by its owner and its value
to him is never the present market price but rather its anticipated
future value.
All this was stimulated by the following from Bill Batt.
BILL BATT
I believe it's to you that we owe the first identification and
explanation of *collectibles* as a kind of speculation to distinguish
them from the kinds of speculation that we link to natural resource
rents. I've just finished reading a review that rivals stories of the
great tulip mania, and one that I don't believe has been thought of by
our Georgist community. It's the late nineties craze over *beanie
babies.*
My wife Karen is a retired pediatrician, and she was given beanie
baby gifts by her patients -- or rather their mothers -- and she still
has quite a few (for whatever they're worth today!).
I have a request of you: to write up the idea of collectibles in
Georgist terms using this episode as an example, so that we all have a
clear understanding of your distinction here. I don't think anyone
other than you ever explicated this idea, and I think it's a profound
one. I think of it somewhat in parallel to the case Dan Sullivan and I
discussed several years ago -- see
http://www.cooperativeindividualism.org/batt-h-william_are-exceptionally-high-wages-really-rent-2002.htm.
There are some stories that you, and you alone, are credited --
another being the peanut sales story in Weston Ontario, which I have
repeated often -- and even used in the appendix of the book that Cliff
Cobb and I amended for David Smiley, Crumbling Foundations.
Anyway, we need you to explain these ideas in full -- rather than
just in passing. Or at least I do.
HP: Back in the 60's I was having dinner with David
Friedman - the son of Milton - and a couple of friends. We got into
a discussion, or rather an argument, about value. David wiped the
floor with me and as I drove my tattered ideas home, I decided I
needed to do a lot more work on value. My present Georgist ideas
weren't good enough.
A short time later, I read about a collectible auction. Somebody
had bought a Rosalie beer can for $4,000. Later, as he was leaving,
someone stopped him and offered him $10,000 for the Rosalie. He
refused.
This is a very peculiar market, I thought, and I looked into it
further. As I recall there were six Rosalie beer cans in existence
in mint condition. Mint condition was important.
I found that collectors hang on to their mint condition
collectibles even when common sense would suggest they sold. They
kept their eyes on the market but they valued their collectible not
at its present market price but at a future anticipated price.
But this described how landholders view their land!
The land market acts like a 'collectible' market. Land is held in
the expectation that next week, next month, next year, it will have
increased in price. (The psychology of collectors is interesting.
Income doesn't matter - future sales price is the only interest.)
Holding land from use parallels holding a 16th century Tiger Maple
desk in the bedroom wrapped in plastic. The kids are not allowed to
do their homework on it and the costs of holding are minimal.
Land held from use as a collectible is not the subject of serious
investment. It is simply fenced and left unused. If property taxes
become a nuisance, the location might be blacktopped for a car lot,
or a valuable corner might support a gas station.
Such uses were once called "taxpayers".
Should an offer arrive that just can't be refused, the blacktop or
the service station can be quickly removed at minimum cost, just as
the tiger maple desk can be unwrapped.
Although, wait a minute! Perhaps next month, or next year, a better
offer might arrive. Better hang on for that future anticipated
value.
Finally, there are "contrived collectibles" - a limited
print edition, or first cover, or 'we broke the mold'. This category
includes beanie babies which can make some millionaires, while
others are left with a garage full of worthless "collectibles".
I suspect that everybody would like to make easy money as a
collector, which leads to mad scrambles after anything that looks
like a possible collectible including homes, but we know about that.
I did think that economists had left the subject of collectibles
alone, but Fred Foldvary sent me a couple of cites.
RETURN
TO PART ONE
|