The People's Economic Scientist
Harry Pollard
[Forward by Harry Pollard to the 2004 abridged
edition of The Science of Political Economy, by Henry George,
published by the Robert Schalkenbach Foundation, 2004]
He was a high school dropout who spurned the Chair of Economics at
the University of California. He was a job printer, but handily
defeated Teddy Roosevelt in a mayoralty contest for the city of New
York.
Leo Tolstoy read him, realized the significance of what he wrote and
tried to persuade the Czar of Russia to adopt his ideas before it was
too late. The Czar did not warm to Tolstoy's plea - and soon it was
too late.
He was known around the world. The Irish enthusiastically cheered his
speeches. Australia and New Zealand introduced his ideas of taxation
to much of their territory, as did Canada's West Coast.
Sun Yat-Sen, called "The Father of Modern China", read him
and declared that the path for China would be his "decentralist
economic ideas". Sun's thinking influenced the Taiwanese, who
introduced widespread land reform based on his economic writings. The
theories were confirmed by practice. Farm production increased so much
that Taiwan, with a population density of more than 1,300 to the
square mile, achieved a net export of food. The London Economist
said that the "miracle of Taiwan" rested on this successful
land reform. Perhaps his greatest influence was found in Britain at
the beginning of the 20th century. Liberal Party policy looked as if
it had been copied from his many books. Churchill declared he had made
speeches by the yard endorsing and promoting this self-taught
economist's policy of taxing land values.
Introduction
At that time, the greatest obstacle to any meaningful legislation was
the House of Lords. The land of Britain was almost entirely held by
fewer than 3,000 landholders - who controlled the Lords. That
unelected body could nullify any legislation passed by the elected
House of Commons.
So, the Liberal Party forced the issue. They put forward the
Parliament Bill, a measure that would cut the claws of the Lords. With
the aid of the Bishops, who sat in the House of Lords, the Parliament
Bill passed by a scant 15 votes. The veto power of the House of Lords
was ended. They could no longer prevent the enactment of a general tax
on land value. This law was passed in 1913, and the process began.
Unfortunately, "the war to end all wars", WWI, began the
following year - and that ended the land value tax legislation. As
part of the price for supporting the war, the Tories demanded that all
controversial legislation be stopped. The process of assessment and
collection of the land value tax was ended and it was never resumed.
The Parliament Bill remains in force until this day, however. For the
last century the House of Lords have been unable to interfere with any
money bill.
They were tumultuous times - and a brash Philadelphian named Henry
George was in the middle of the tumult, because he had the nerve to
write clear, comprehensible books on how the economy works.
He entered the scene with
Progress and Poverty, published in 1879. After a slow start it
took hold and millions of copies were sold. It was a book of economics
like no other. He questioned everything. His opening shot showed the
intention of his thinking: "Why do wages tend to a minimum that
will give but a bare living?"
It is striking that more than a century later, the question is no
longer asked in modern economics. The modern War on Poverty has
already been lost and its soldiers spend their time treating the
casualties.
Such failure was not good enough for George. Again and again he
hammered home a query. Why, he wanted to know, with the enormous
increase in the power to produce, is it so hard to make a living?
He was, perhaps, the first labor economist, but one who did not mince
his words as he discussed wages and unemployment. "Why are people
looking for jobs," he thundered, "Why are not jobs looking
for people?"
His concern for the condition of labor did not blind him to the need
for scientific methodology. He began correctly at the beginning, by
carefully defining the basic terms of economic science. Not for him
the loose meanings that lead to loose thinking. During this process he
was properly unkind to icons in the science such as Adam Smith, David
Ricardo and John Stuart Mill, demonstrating how their less than
accurate use of terms sent them on false journeys.
George did his job properly. He began with a concept and defined it,
which meant putting a fence around it. He then placed a label on the
things within the fence. When he had finished, he had terms that
contained within them everything on earth - indeed, everything in the
universe. There was no fence-straddling. There would be no confusion
in the language of his new study, which he named The Science of
Political Economy.
His study did not lean on the use of mathematics. Rather, he relied
on everyday language, so that all his theories could be understood by
anyone who could read. This meant that his reasoning was clear and
could be accepted, or attacked, by any thinking person.
The attacks came from those at whom his finger pointed. Yet,
overwhelmingly, his books achieved acceptance and wielded influence
around the world.
Even to the present - for when Russia dispensed with communism, eight
Nobel Prize-winning economists wrote a letter to the president
suggesting that Russia's basic problems could be dealt with by
application of the ideas of Henry George. At the moment in Britain,
discussion of George's ideas can be heard from local town councils to
Parliament.
The Science of Political Economy draws on his thinking from
several books. Within this volume is synthesized the essence of
economics as a science. His ability to move from the simple to the
complex, connecting every point by a mixture of logic and observation,
lays before us a canvas that shows us the whole picture.
Henry George died before the book was completed. The original
publication was finished by the author's son from notes. In this new
edition, Lindy Davies has carefully edited and tightened the
manuscript to provide us with a work of which the author would have
approved.
HARRY POLLARD has been teaching the science of
political economy for more than fifty years. He has taught in the
classroom, on radio and television, and in public forums. He is the
author of the popular InterStudent Economic Courses, which have been
widely used in California high schools since the 1970s.
Robert Schalkenbach
Foundation
|