Accounting for Nature
Sandra Postel
[Reprinted from WorldWatch Magazine,
March-April, 1991]
Judging from economic statistics, the latter half of the 20th century
has been a period of remarkable success for the world. Between 1950
and 1990, the global economy expanded fivefold, per-capita income more
than doubled, and material consumption soared to new heights.
But this unparalleled prosperity has come at great environmental
expense. Health-threatening air pollution, contaminated drinking
water, a thinning ozone shield, and the buildup of climate-disrupting
greenhouse gases are among the uncounted costs of economic expansion.
These problems arise largely from the failure of economies to
incorporate environmental damages into public and private decisions --
whether to generate electricity from coal or sunlight, for instance,
or to commute by car or public transportation. As a result, society
has ended up bearing these costs, often in unanticipated ways. U.S.
citizens annually incur an estimated $40 billion in damages from
unhealthy levels of air pollution, but car drivers pay nothing at the
gas pump for their part in this assault.
At the same time, government decision makers, preoccupied with
economic growth, are often blind to the ecological price of their
pursuits. Rapid clearing of forests for timber export may increase
gross national product but eventually will cause untallied costs in
soil erosion, water supply disruption, reduced biological diversity,
and hastened climatic change.
If the world economy currently wreaks such environmental havoc, then
how can we design a vibrant, ecologically sound alternative? The
answer may be found in the tortuous maze of government fiscal policy,
where many environmental problems now begin. By curtailing subsidies
that foster the misuse or destruction of resources, creating
incentives for ecologically beneficial activities, and imposing taxes
on environmentally damaging practices, we can steer ourselves toward a
more promising future.
Government-Financed Destruction
A surprising number of public policies are stacked squarely against
the environment. Hidden subsidies for automobile use, utility
regulations biased against conservation, underpriced irrigation water,
and below-cost timber sales are but a few of the numerous public
programs that result in serious environmental damage. Collectively,
governments spend tens of billions of dollars a year supporting
environmentally unsound economic practices.
In the Third World, tax exemptions and discounted prices for
pesticides provide one example of these misguided incentives. In
examining policies among nine developing countries in Asia, Africa,
and Latin America, economist Robert Repetto of the World Resources
Institute in Washington, D.C., found pesticide subsidies in the early
1980s ranging from 19 percent of the unsubsidized retail cost (in
China) to 89 percent (in Senegal). The Egyptian government spent more
per capita on pesticide subsidies in 1982 than it currently spends on
health.
By keeping pesticide costs low, governments aim to help farmers
reduce pest damage and thereby increase crop yields. But they also
encourage farmers to use pesticides excessively, increasing the number
of chemical-related deaths and illnesses and releasing more pollutants
into the environment. Moreover, subsidies inhibit the development and
use of integrated pest management (IPM), a package of measures
designed to control pests in a safer, more ecologically sound way.
IPM makes use of natural predators of pests, different planting
patterns, pest-resistant crop varieties, and other non-chemical
controls to stabilize and even increase harvests while minimizing
hazards to health and the environment. Under this integrated approach,
farmers use chemicals selectively and only when necessary. IPM has
proved effective with soybeans in Brazil, with cotton in China,
Nicaragua, and Texas, and with cassava in equatorial Africa [see "To
Kill a Mealybug" on page 37]. A far-reaching program for
Indonesian rice growers slashed the use of insecticides by nearly 60
percent within a year. Average rice yields among farmers trained in
IPM rose from 2.7 tons per acre to 3.3 tons.
Similarly, forests have suffered in rich and poor countries alike
from government efforts to promote economic growth. Laden with debt
and looking for quick revenues, many tropical-country governments --
often aided by international donors -- have offered fiscal incentives
to encourage the conversion of forests to pasture, cash crops, and
other land uses that may earn immediate profits bur rarely prove
sustainable on poor tropical soils. Harvesting contracts overly
favorable to loggers have fueled "timber booms" that not
only deplete and degrade forests but open larger areas to the further
depredations of unsustainable farming and ranching.
Brazil, Indonesia, and the Philippines are among the countries
draining their treasuries of $500 million to more than $1 billion
annually because of such policies. Much of the deforestation of the
Brazilian Amazon can be linked to government road-building,
resettlement schemes, and income tax credits for the conversion of
forest to pasture or other land uses.
Recent deforestation trends in Brazil suggest how rapidly change can
occur once government inducements are removed. In 1988, most tax
credits that encouraged large-scale forest clearing were suspended.
Satellite images show that annual deforestation rates in the Amazon
peaked in 1987 at 20 million acres, dropped to 12 million in 1988 and
continued sliding to 7.4 million in 1989 (the most recent year for
which figures are available). An unusually rainy dry season, when most
of the jungle burning takes place, coupled with stepped-up enforcement
against illegal burning, helped stem the loss in 1989, but the
government's shift in fiscal policy undoubtedly played a role.
In addition to environmental benefits, reducing such subsidies often
eases social inequities and frees funds for programs that benefit the
poor. Most incentives currently enrich the politically powerful, who
can successfully lobby for economic favors. Pesticide subsidies and
underpriced irrigation water, for instance, do nothing for the
cash-poor, dryland farmer who has no access to these inputs. Likewise,
subsidies for cattle ranching and logging typically bypass those on
the lower economic rungs.
Rewarding Do-Gooders
Moving the economy toward sustainability will require more than just
eliminating government incentives for environmentally destructive
activities. It also involves creating rewards for ecologically sound
practices. Such an approach demands a systematic look at how current
rules, regulations, and incentives shape behavior, and how they can be
changed to encourage sound decisions.
Positive incentives can do much, for example, to reinvigorate Third
World family planning efforts, which have been badly neglected over
the last decade. Setting up education savings accounts for the
children of couples who limit their family size, allowing higher
income tax deductions for couples with no more than two children, and
providing free family planning services are but a few of the ways to
encourage smaller families.
Well-designed incentive programs are cost-effective, since
expenditures to reduce fertility levels avoid larger social service
costs later on. In Mexico, for example, every peso spent on family
planning by the urban social security system between 1972 and 1984
saved nine pesos that would have been spent on maternal and infant
health care. By providing nearly 800,000 women with contraceptives,
the program averted 3.6 million unwanted births and resulted in a net
savings of some 318 billion pesos ($2 billion).
In the energy area, reforming the way utilities are regulated could
unleash the vast money-saving potential of energy efficiency, while at
the same time slowing global warming, reducing acid rain, and curbing
urban air pollution. Under most current regulations, utility profits
rise in tandem with electricity sales. Even though utilities could
save energy more cheaply than supplying more -- by encouraging the
installation of efficient lighting, low-flow showerheads that reduce
the use of hot water, and insulation in homes and offices -- they have
little incentive to do so.
In the United States, new programs in California, New York, Oregon,
and five New England states are "de-coupling" profits from
power sales and giving utilities a financial reason to invest in
conservation. Under a new California program, three regulated
utilities will be allowed to profit more from investing in
conservation than from selling additional electricity. Together, these
efficiency programs will cost an estimated $500 million over the next
two years but are expected to save more than twice that in reduced
power bills.
Efficiency improvements have an enormous untapped potential in
developing countries as well, even though their per-capita energy use
is tar lower than that in industrial countries. For example, Brazil
could cut its growth in electricity use in half over the next two
decades by promoting efficient technologies, according to energy
analyst Howard Geller at the American Council for an Energy-Efficient
Economy. Indeed, by encouraging conservation and efficiency
investments -- instead of subsidizing energy use -- developing
countries could avoid more than $1.4 trillion in energy production
costs over the next 20 years, saving scarce capital and improving the
environment.
Making Polluters Pay
Equally important as redirecting government incentives is taking
steps to correct the market's failure to capture the full costs of
pollution, waste, and resource depletion.
Most governments have dealt with this shortcoming by setting
regulations, such as requiring that power plants install equipment to
capture air pollutants or that factories treat their wastewater in a
specified manner before releasing it into nearby rivers and streams.
This approach has measurably improved the environment in many cases
and is especially important where high-risk activities are concerned,
such as disposing of radioactive waste or safeguarding an endangered
species from extinction. But it is often a costly and cumbersome way
of attaining broad societal aims.
A powerful instrument for fostering environmentally sound economic
activity lies in the realm of taxation. While new taxes are unpopular
politically, opinion polls show that a good share of the public thinks
more should be spent on protecting the environment. By shifting the
tax base away from income and toward environmentally damaging
activities, governments can reflect new priorities without necessarily
increasing the total tax burden. And because taxes adjust prices and
let the market do the rest, they can help meet many environmental
goals efficiently.
Restructuring the tax base in this way has many advantages.
Governments typically raise the bulk of their revenues by taxing
income, profits, and the value added to goods and services. This has
the unintended effect of discouraging work, savings, and investment
--things that are generally good for an economy. If governments
substituted taxes on pollution, waste, and resource depletion for a
large portion of current levies, both the environment and the economy
could benefit.
Many nations have already established so-called green taxes. A survey
by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development -- a
governmental organization of industrial, free-market countries --
found more than 50 separate green taxes among 14 of its 23 members,
including levies on air and water pollution, waste, noise, and
potentially harmful products such as fertilizers and batteries. In
most cases, however, these fees have been set too low to motivate
major changes in behavior. Norway's charge on fertilizers and
pesticides, for instance, raises funds for programs in sustainable
agriculture -- certainly a worthy cause -- but is too low to encourage
farmers to cut their chemical use.
A comprehensive environmental tax code would alter economic activity
in many areas. It would place fees on carbon emissions from the
burning of coal, oil, and natural gas, and thereby slow global
warming; it would penalize the use of virgin materials, and thus
encourage recycling and reuse; it would charge for the generation of
toxic waste, and so foster waste reduction and the development of
safer products; it would tax emissions of sulfur and nitrogen oxides,
and therefore curb acid rain; and it would impose levies on the
overpumping of groundwater, thus encouraging efficient water use.
An analysis of eight possible green taxes for the United States -- on
carbon emissions, hazardous waste, paper produced from virgin pulp,
pesticide sales, sulfur and nitrogen oxides emissions,
chlorofluorocarbon (CFC) sales, and groundwater depletion -- suggests
that they can raise substantial revenues while working to protect the
environment (see box). Determining tax levels that reduce harm to
human health and the environment without damaging the economy is a
complicated task; the ones shown here are simply for illustration.
Because some taxes have multiple effects (a carbon tax, for example,
would lower both carbon and sulfur dioxide emissions by discouraging
fossil fuel consumption) and because the taxed activities will decline
even before taxes are fully in place, revenues shown in the box cannot
be neatly totaled. But it seems likely that the eight levies listed
here could raise $100 billion to $150 billion, or 25 to 35 percent of
the current government revenue from personal income taxes.
On the Political Agenda
In late September 1990, the 12 environment ministers from the
European Community (EC) gathered in Rome to discuss the possibility of
community-wide green taxes. Though they failed to reach agreement, the
idea seems likely to stay alive. The European Commission, the
policymaking arm of the European Community, supports a common EC tax
on carbon emissions, as do Belgium, Denmark, France, and Germany.
However, the less wealthy EC members fear that a harmonized tax would
be too high, jeopardizing their growth; the Netherlands worries that
it might be too low.
Both Finland and the Netherlands instituted taxes on carbon emissions
from fossil fuels in early 1990; Norway and Sweden were scheduled to
begin collecting carbon taxes in January. Unfortunately, none of these
levies is high enough to spur major changes in energy use. Now that
more than a dozen industrial nations are committed to slowing the pace
of global warming, higher charges will almost certainly be needed to
reduce carbon dioxide emissions.
In the United States, several energy taxes were proposed in 1990.
With little support for energy efficiency coming from the Bush
administration, all that Congress approved was a meager 5 cents
per-gallon increase in the federal gasoline tax, which will not reduce
energy use or carbon emissions substantially.
Adjustments for the Poor
Completely shifting the tax base away from income taxes and toward
green taxes would be undesirable, since income taxes are usually
designed to make the wealthy pay proportionately more; green taxes, in
contrast, may hit the poor the hardest. Hefty carbon charges, for
instance, would cause hearing oil prices to rise, imposing a heavy
burden on low-income households. To offset this undesirable impact,
income tax rates would need to be lowered even more for poorer people.
Government payments could compensate the very poor, who may not pay
any income taxes at all now but who might experience higher living
costs under an environmental tax code.
Another reason a blend of income and environmental taxes is best is
that green-tax revenues would diminish as production and consumption
patterns shift away from taxed activities. Therefore, environmental
taxes would not be as constant a source of revenue over time as income
taxes are. Once businesses and consumers have adjusted to the new tax
scheme, revenues from green taxes and income taxes would strike a more
stable balance.
Beyond National Borders
Besides their help in reshaping national economies, green taxes can
play an important role in international initiatives to deal with
global environmental threats. In 1989, for example, the United States
started taxing sales of CFCs to help meet its commitment to phase out
production of these ozone-depicting substances by the year 2000.
Green taxes can also raise funds for global initiatives that require
transfers from rich countries to poorer ones, including slowing global
warming, preserving tropical forests and biological diversity, and
protecting the ozone shield. Such transfers would serve as partial
payment for the ecological debt industrial countries have incurred by
causing most of the damage to the global environment thus far. The
creation of a new financing mechanism of this kind will be high on the
agenda of the U.N. Conference on Environment and Development to be
held in Brazil in 1992.
A step in this direction was taken in September 1989, when the
international community agreed to set up an environmental fund to be
managed by the World Bank in cooperation with the U.N. Development
Program and the U.N. Environment Program. The aim is to raise more
than $1 billion for the first three years. While this is a start, much
more will be required to aid Third World countries with the energy,
forestry, family planning, and other investments needed to move the
global economy onto a sustainable track. An extra tax of $10 per ton
of carbon emitted in industrial nations (excluding economically
strapped Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union) would initially generate
$25 billion per year for an expanded global fund.
Reshaping fiscal policy to be an instrument of environmental
restoration may be difficult at a time when policymakers are concerned
with the economic slowdown in much of the world and with revitalizing
the flagging economies of the former Soviet bloc. Yet nothing lasting
will be gained by the continued pursuit of growth at the environment's
expense. Capitalism may stand victorious over socialism as the better
way of organizing a modern industrial economy, but the challenge of
building an environmentally sustainable economy has just begun.
The Not-For-Everglades?
Looking down on the heart of south Florida's Everglades, the watery
wilderness seems anything but threatened. Huge flocks of snow-white
ibis, wings glistening in the afternoon sun, take flight against a
backdrop of gentle sawgrass prairie spreading as far as the eye can
see. The Everglades, known as "grassy water" to the region's
native Americans, remains one of the world's largest freshwater
wetlands.
Unfortunately, scientists say time is running out for this unique
wilderness. The Everglades ecosystem, now a shadow of its former self,
is buckling under pressure from pollution and the siphoning of its
water to meet the demands of agriculture and a growing state
population. According to Robert Arnsberger, assistant superintendent
of Everglades National Park, the stressed-out system "could
ecologically fail within the next 20 years."
Historically, the Everglades watershed began north of Lake Okeechobee
in the Kissimmee River basin. Heavy summer rains flooded the lake and
surrounding marshes, causing a broad sheet of water a few feet deep
and up to 40 miles wide to flow slowly south to the Gulf of Mexico
through the sawgrass, cypress swamps, and other vegetation that make
up the diverse Everglades. A dry winter period followed, when water
supplies contracted to scattered shallow pools.
Many plants and animals have come to depend on this seasonal water
cycle for their existence, including the wood stork -- one of 14
endangered wildlife species surviving in Everglades National Park.
This natural pattern began to unravel during this century, as vast
areas of south Florida's swamps were drained for farmland and urban
development.
Only about half of the original 4 million acres of wetland remains,
500,000 of it in the 1.5 million acres that make up the park.
A vast system of canals, dikes, levees and pump stations -- 80
percent of it federally funded and built by the U.S. Army Corps of
Engineers -- now controls flooding and diverts water for agriculture,
coastal residents, and tourists. This has greatly altered the natural
water flow. As a result, populations of nesting wading birds --
including herons, egrets, ibis, and wood storks -- have plummeted 90
percent, from some 300,000 in the 1930s to no more than 30,000 today.
Pollution raises concerns for the Everglades' future as well. Some
700,000 acres of agricultural land just south of Lake Okeechobee --
nearly two-thirds of it in sugar cane -- not only claim the lion's
share of south Florida's water but also release runoff contaminated
with nitrogen and phosphorus into adjacent wetlands. Elevated levels
of these nutrients foster the growth of cattails, which have clogged
waterways and caused shifts in the natural vegetation on as many as
30,000 acres over the last three decades. Wetlands filter out most of
the excess nutrients before they reach the park, but continued heavy
loads could cause a pollution front to move south, tipping the park's
ecological balance.
In an unusual twist, the federal government has filed a lawsuit
against the South Florida Water Management District, the agency
operating the regional water system, and other state officials,
claiming that their lack of enforcement of state water quality
standards has put at risk both Everglades National Park and the
federally owned Loxahatchee National Wildlife Refuge, also located in
the Everglades watershed. At the heart of the matter, which was still
unresolved as of January, are the phosphorus loads from sugar cane
fields and vegetable farms entering wetlands 70 miles north of the
park.
Last September, the management district adopted a blueprint to
protect the Everglades. Now steeped in controversy, the Surface Water
Improvement and Management (SWIM) Plan attempts to address the water
quantity and quality problems threatening Everglades National Park. It
calls for a 75-percent reduction in phosphorus loadings from the
agricultural area into adjacent marshes, from an average of 222 tons a
year to 56 tons. Toward this end, 18,000 acres of sugar cane and sod
farms would be converted into wetlands to help absorb excess
nutrients.
Studies by Curtis J. Richardson and colleagues at the Duke University
Wetland Center suggest, however, that some 560 acres of marsh are
needed to reclaim one ton of phosphorus on a sustained basis. Meeting
the SWIM plan target would therefore require about 93,000 acres of
restored wetlands -- five times the area provided for in the plan. The
management district, however, contests the applicability of these
findings.
Even if pollution is adequately abated, the timing and amount of
water entering the park pose immediate threats to its integrity. At
least partial restoration of the natural water cycle is crucial to
halting the habitat degradation and wildlife declines scientists have
documented. In 1990, Congress appropriated $15 million for a 107,000
acre expansion of the park's eastern boundary and asked the Army Corps
of Engineers to develop a plan for re-creating original water patterns
there. Additional help may come from a $500,000 federal study that
will evaluate ways to improve the park's water supply.
With so many overlapping interests, federal and state agencies need
to work toward a partnership. Yet the federal government's decision to
slap a lawsuit on state officials seems a costly distraction from the
need to remedy the harm done by projects it built. At the state level,
conservation measures are essential. Florida residents use an average
of 200 gallons of water per person per day, twice the national
average. Farmers are charged nothing for their water use, and so have
no incentive to conserve.
Saving the Everglades represents a crucial test of whether a region's
people and economy can adapt to the ecological needs of an
irreplaceable natural area. Decisions made now will determine whether
this treasured wilderness gets a fighting chance.
|