A Criticism of Mr. Henry George
Arnold Toynbee
[The first of two lectures delivered in St. Andrew's
Hall, London, January 1883]
PREFATORY NOTE.
When Mr. Toynbee delivered the two
speeches which make up this pamphlet, it was his intention to use
the shorthand writer's report of what he said as the basis of a
treatise, containing a fuller statement of his arguments, and, in
particular, a large number of statistical details, of which in
speaking he only indicated the general results. A protracted and, as
it has proved, fatal illness frustrated his purpose. Mr. Toynbee was
never able so much as to look over the proofs of his addresses, to
assure himself that he was correctly reported, much less to review
and recast what he said. Delivered as they were in the extremity of
physical weakness, and now appearing without revision, these
speeches may well seem to those who knew him best to be but an
imperfect expression of his thought and aims. Nevertheless, the
friend to whom the task of editing them has fallen has not felt
himself justified in making any but the most trifling and obvious
corrections. There were, indeed, no materials for a more complete
revision, as the speeches were entirely extempore, and Mr. Toynbee
was not in the habit of making notes of his addresses. The
excellence of the shorthand writer's notes permits the hope that
there may be no serious errors in the report of what Mr. Toynbee
actually said, however far this may fall short of what, had strength
not failed him, he was competent and anxious to say. But any regrets
on this score are now merged in the wider and lasting regret for all
that has been lost to his friends and the community by his untimely
death. -- A. M.
The book I have undertaken to criticise does not stand alone in
economic and social literature. It is one of many similar works which
have been inspired by a vision of human misery. It is true that it is
not filled, like the work of the great socialist, Karl Marx, with
detailed descriptions of human degradation; nevertheless, it has human
injustice for its theme. Some of us, I know, are inclined to put the
book down in disgust and impatience; but I think any of us who have,
even for a moment, looked into the abyss will be glad that this book
has once more reminded us of the widespread suffering that is
concealed beneath the smooth surface of our ordinary life. I know that
many who have read this book have felt not merely disgust and
impatience, but have thought that the warm and fierce sympathy shown
in it with human pain was not real; but they have made a great
mistake.
I do not think we now require such books as these to make us realise
and understand those more obvious forms of suffering which press upon
us from every side. We are all of us, I suppose, appalled when we
picture the dark and desolate cabins of Maamtrasna, on that bleak
mountain side, inhabited by half-civilised savages, or when we visit
those still more dark and desolate corners of this great city,
inhabited by beings whom we still call men and women, or when we catch
a glimpse of the moral interior of a labourer's cottage. These forms
of suffering, I say, are obvious -- they are obtrusive; but it is a
more refined form of suffering which, it seems to me, this book brings
to our notice. It is the suffering of men who earn what we call good
wages, whose labour -- labour, let me remind you, which does not
invigorate the brain, but which wears it out prematurely, and
depresses the mind and dulls the intellect - whose labour, I say,
cannot obtain for them even a whole house as a home, nor the decent
enjoyments of life, nor the certainty of an honourable old age. Forty
years ago it was the famished multitude clamouring for bread that
threatened society. To-day, though we still have our 800,000 paupers,
and hundreds of thousands more who are kept from pauperism only by
heroic sacrifice, to-day, I say, society is threatened not by this
multitude, for cheap bread has kept them quiet since 1846, but it is
threatened by that large class of men whose wants have grown while
their income has been stationary, or whose wants have grown faster
than their incomes.
I know that there are some, again, who will say that this description
is exaggerated, and I admit that there are classes of artisans --
stone carvers, for example -- whose wages are high, and who find
rational delight in their employment; but I maintain that any people
who have visited factories, or descended into mines, any person who
has taken the trouble to compare the necessary expenditure of an
artisan with his income, will understand that what I say is true. The
misery, however, which produced the socialism with which we are
familiar in England was misery, in the first instance, of a physical
kind. All modern socialism originated with the great industrial
revolution which began at the commencement of the last century; the
industrial revolution which silenced the spinning-wheel and hand-loom,
and dragged men and women into great cities and huge factories. With
that began the modern problems of the distribution of wealth; and also
at that time great socialist writers made their appearance; but the
same epoch which gave birth to the socialists, gave birth also to
their great enemies, the economists.
These writers - Malthus, James Mill, David Ricardo -- men of
intellect and of upright character, framed an explanation of the
misery which they saw before them, which denied hope to the human
race. One man, the most eminent of them, Ricardo, caught up the
scattered points which various writers had elucidated, and welded them
into a compact and lucid science No writer that I know has a greater
power of abstract thought than David Ricardo, and I have found it
difficult, if once you grant his premises, to find any mistakes in his
conclusions. From 1817 to 1848 the economists reigned supreme. There
were, indeed, objections raised, objections raised even by men in
their own ranks. Sismondi, the great Swiss economist, for example,
once talking to Ricardo, said, "What, then, is wealth everything?
is man nothing?" Ricardo answered -- at least you will find the
answer in his books -- that the suffering which Sismondi pitied was
the result of an inevitable law.
To explain the views which the economists took, we must remember that
they looked upon life as a mad race between population and wealth.
They would not allow for a moment that the machinery in the factories
was to be stopped in order that women and children might breathe, lest
a little wealth should be lost, and the world go back. There were
others who protested outside the ranks of the economists. There were
the Christian socialists, there was Thomas Carlyle, who in his Past
and Present flung upon the economists passionate reproaches, which
all of them left unheeded but one, and that man was John Stuart Mill.
In 1848 was published Mill's book, which, though it incorporates much
of the old economic doctrines, yet represents an immense and
unparalleled advance in England of union and of sympathy with the mass
of the people. In that book, for the first time, is seen the influence
of the socialists upon the economists; the influence of the earliest
social reformers, who, bewildered and perplexed as they were, said
that a science that told them these things must be a false science.
And since Mill's time, the argument has gone on, and at last it is now
apparent to all the world, that the long and bitter controversy
between economists and human beings has ended in the conversion of the
economists. The economist now dares to say that the end of his
practical science is not wealth, but man; and further, he owns that
his intellectual theories have also undergone a vast change. He has
learnt to recognise that the laws which he supposed were universal are
often only partial and provisional; he has learnt to recognise that
the method which he uses with such confidence -- the method of
abstract deduction -- is a most dangerous one; that it can be used
only by men who know that at every step they have to question their
premises, and that at every step they have to test their conclusions
by experience. Last of all, he recognises that the vast problems which
we all now see are looming upon us cannot be solved by rash and hasty
statements, but only by patient and vigilant science. He recognises
that to solve the problem of to-day we must go back far into the past.
He recognises that the problem of distribution is not a simple one;
that it is a very difficult and a very complicated one. That is the
position of the economists at the present time; but it is a singular
thing, that at the very time when David Ricardo has been discredited
amongst the economists themselves, he has become the founder of two
new systems of socialism. He, the great middle-class economist, the
man who was looked up to as the bulwark of society, this man by his
theory of wages has produced Lassalle, and by his theory of rent has
produced Henry George. To-night I have nothing to do with Lassalle, I
have to speak of Mr. Henry George.
The book which Mr. George wrote between 1877 and 1879 is, as we all
know, a remarkable one. It is full of acute dialectic and splendid
declamation; full, as I said in my opening remarks, of a real and keen
sympathy with the people. Indeed, as he tells us in his book, he might
well sympathise with the people, for he had been a workman himself.
Nevertheless, remarkable as the book is, original as the book is --
not so original as many of us suppose, not so original if we come to
look back upon American economic literature -- it has yet, in spite of
partial truths, promulgated errors which I believe to be fundamentally
dangerous. And I, for one, seeing how much wrong the economists have
done in the past by false theories, remembering that the economists
for years denounced Trades Unions, and told the unionists that they
could not raise the rate of wages by combination; remembering that the
economists have sometimes influenced legislation in the past in a
mischievous direction, that they were guilty, for instance, of the
Irish Land Act of i860, which substituted contract for tenure; I am
determined that, as far as in me lies, I will be no party to any more
illusions. I will do what I can to further the public good, but I will
not sacrifice my intellectual conscience by supporting a fair, but
delusive panacea.
The book which I have spoken of was written in 1877, but it was
preceded by a pamphlet, which was written in 1871. I said just now
that George was a child of David Ricardo, but that is an inadequate
statement; we must also recognise that he is the child, or rather,
that his theories are the children, of the peculiar circumstances of a
new State. The first pamphlet which Mr. George wrote was a pamphlet
about the Land Question in California. And it is no wonder that he
should have written the pamphlet, for he saw in a country with natural
resources greater than those of France, and with a population at that
time numbering not more than 600,000 people, tramps and paupers make
their appearance. That was enough to make a man gasp and stare. He
also saw the concentration of land in a few hands - one peculiar evil,
that is to say, of an old country making its appearance in a new one.
Properties there were at the time which exceeded almost anything we
know in England, properties of more than a quarter of a million acres
held by men who did not even go through the pretence of rendering any
public service as the condition of their tenure.
Mr. George pondered on these things, and whilst he was pondering, he
stumbled across Mill's pamphlets, published in 1870, on the reform of
land tenure. In those pamphlets Mill for the first time put forward
the famous proposal for the appropriation of the unearned increment.
But the proposal was not a new one. It is to be found in the first
edition of Mill's book, published in 1848, and it is to be found still
further back than that in his father's book on political economy,
published in 1821. The history of the idea is a singular one, for
there is no doubt that it was the historian of British India with whom
the idea originated. It was his observations on the systems of land
tenure and revenue in India that led him to make, in a clear and
incisive form, the proposal which has now been popularised and become
the basis of an agitation. That proposal put forward in Mill's
pamphlet- awakened new thoughts in Mr. George. It awakened also new
thoughts in land reformers in Victoria and our own colonies. All over
the world men were busy with the idea, fighting then for its practical
application.
Mr. George's pamphlet, though a very remarkable one, appears to have
produced little effect. His practical proposals were two. First, he
said, "We will tax all land up to its full value." By that
he meant that he would take all that part of rent which is due to the
growth of civilisation and to wealth, and not to individual labour and
enterprise.
Let us remember that that is the proposal -- to take, mark you, not
what a man puts into the soil, but what comes to a man owing to no
exertion on his own part. "If," said Mr. George, "you
tax these great estates up to their full value, then it will be
impossible any longer for the great landowners to keep their
properties together; they will be forced to sell." In the next
place, he proposed, and it was a remarkable proposal to make, to limit
the size of properties -- that is to say, that land in future should
be granted only in 40 and 50 acre sections; and he believed that in
that way a steady and regular development of population and wealth
would take place. I want you to remember that proposition, because Mr.
George abandoned it afterwards. His pamphlet attracted some attention,
but produced, as I said, little effect. Mr. George, however, did not
abandon his consideration of the question. He turned to other American
economists; he studied the writings of Henry Carey, the Pennsylvanian
economist; of Francis Walker, the eminent head of the United States
Department of Statistics; of Francis Bowen, another American
economist; and of M. Emile de Laveleye.
All these books he had studied, when in the year 1877 there came the
great labour war in Pennsylvania. That labour war in Pennsylvania, and
the distress that followed, led Mr. George to begin this great work,
which he completed two years afterwards. Remember that the work was
begun at a time of immense distress, and of widespread and deep
depression of trade. In 1878, for example, it was said that 600,000
men left the East for the West. Everywhere wages fell, and artisans
who had emigrated from England to America returned from America to
England. It was in the midst, therefore, of an unexampled depression
of trade, in a continent with the greatest natural resources in the
world, that this book was written. Again, remember that these
circumstances must have left their mark upon the treatise. And note,
too, that Mr. George's practical proposals are now a little changed
from those of 1871. His first practical proposal is still to
confiscate rent -- i.e., to take the unearned increment without
compensation; but, on the other hand, he abandons his old proposal of
limiting the size of farms, and asserts that large farms are due to an
inevitable law of economic development, with which he will not meddle.
This is the book which I have to criticise. It abounds with points,
it abounds with side issues; but there is one main contention, and one
principal theory. The contention is, that rent must be taken, and the
theory is a theory of the development of society in relation to the
distribution of wealth. That not only for Mr. George, but for all of
us, is the main issue ; that is the real question -- Is the law of
economic development one which will tend to produce greater and
greater equality in the distribution of wealth, or is it one which
will concentrate wealth more and more in a few hands? Now we know that
in England wealth has become gradually concentrated in fewer hands.
The fact has been disputed, and it is not such a simple question as
some people suppose; but still, if we take the evidence of the most
competent persons, we shall find that upon this point they agree.
There was a famous Budget speech made by Mr. Gladstone in 1864, a
speech in which, after dilating upon the unexampled prosperity of the
country. Air. Gladstone paused, and turned round and said to his
astonished audience, "But what is human life in the great
majority of cases but a bare struggle for existence?" And the
remark was repeated in less emphatic, but equally significant,
language only the other day by the latest member of the Cabinet, Sir
Charles Dilke. We have, therefore, the evidence both of Mr. Gladstone,
the Prime Minister, and Sir Charles Dilke, that wealth is concentrated
in fewer hands, or, at any rate, that the mass of the people do not
share in the growing prosperity of our industry and our commerce. And
the same phenomenon was visible in America in those two years of which
I speak. There, also, was the spectacle of men like Vanderbilt. who
inherited twenty millions, and of others almost equally rich, who,
whilst the labourers were driven by thousands from the East to the
West, still lived in luxury, and seemed to have kept the wealth which
they had made.
What is the explanation? What is the explanation of this ever-
recurring question; the question which has bewildered the minds and
saddened the hearts of every man who cares for his fellowmen? The
explanation must be one of four things. Either there is an impassable,
inexorable physical limit, which presses down the labourers, and
against which the labourers struggle in vain. Or, there must be some
fatal flaw in our institutions. Or, there must be some sinister shadow
cast by the law of production -- by the system of production on a
large scale. That system which for production is most efficient may
perhaps cause a more unequal distribution of wealth. Or, last of all,
the fault may be in human nature; it may be that it is human rapacity
-- the apparently inexorable demand of men to benefit themselves at
the expense of their fellow-creatures. One of these four or a
combination of these four must be the cause. Mr. George says that the
explanation is not to be found in any limit set by external nature;
that it is not to be found in all institutions or some, but only in
one -- private property in land. And he expressly denies that the
economic structure of society can have any influence; and further, he
thinks that if you once stamped out that one baneful institution,
human nature would be powerless to oppress and degrade. Of the four
possible kinds of cause Mr. George accordingly only acknowledges the
second, namely, our institutions, and only one part of these -- i.e.,
private property in land.
Is Mr. George right about the first statement? That is our first
point. Remember that at present, for the purposes of to-night, I am
speaking of new countries, not of old countries; I shall deal with old
countries in my next lecture. Is Mr. George right with regard to
America when he says there is no present physical limit to the
prosperity of the people?
Yes, Mr. George is right with regard to America. In the first place,
it has long been recognised by economists, that in manufactures there
is what is called a law of increasing return -- that is, as men come
together in masses, the cost of carriage is diminished, the .power of
combination is increased, inventions take place, and enterprise
advances ; and all these things increase the net produce of labour per
head, ie., the wealth left over after the exertions which have
produced it have been satisfied and the tools and materials replaced.
That is the view of Mr. Nassau Senior, and it is the view, also, of
most English economists -- not, I think, that they have seen its
significance.
Let us turn next to agriculture. Is this law true of agriculture? An
Englishman -- any Englishman who has read, for example, Ricardo's
book, and remembers the ploughing up of the sheep-walks in the years
of the great war with Napoleon, when we got five or six bushels of
wretched corn to the acre -- would think that it is not true, and that
in agriculture, at any rate, there is a law of diminishing return.
After a time, even in a new State, even in a new continent like
America, the return to the labour expended on the fields must be less
and less in proportion to the effort. But of America as a whole this
is not yet true. There are apparent exceptions, due to the
peculiarities of American agriculture, due to the wasteful and
exhausting method of cultivation pursued in America, which has led to
a premature diminution of the fertility of the soil, not only in the
Eastern States, but in what is called the new North-West. Still, on
the whole, we may say that up to the present time not only has the
total wealth of America increased, in agriculture as well as in
manufactures, but -- and this is the crucial point -- the total wealth
per head. Not only is there more wealth, but if it were equally
divided each man would have more. So far, then, we agree with Mr.
George. If, therefore, external nature does not impose a barrier, why
is it, asks Mr. George, that, with all this vast increase of wealth,
wages either do not increase or actually decrease? Who gets this vast
accession of wealth?
Mr. George answers: not the great speculators, not the Rothschilds,
not the great contractors, not the lords of the loom and the spindle,
not the great ironmasters, not the keepers of great stores, not the
great grain dealers and merchants, but one class alone, the owners of
land. They alone seize upon the increase, and are rich, whilst the
people become poorer, or, at least, remain as poor as ever. To some,
perhaps, accustomed to the accumulation of wealth in England, this may
seem an absolutely absurd statement; but let us be patient, and study
Mr. George's book in his own country. If we turn to an eminent
American economist, to whom I have already alluded, Mr. Francis Bowen,
we find that he makes this remark -- that the commonest and the
simplest way of making a fortune in America is to buy up land where a
city is likely to be built, and to wait for an increase in value. And,
again, let us also remember this, in justice to Mr. George's view,
that the great railway kings in America have not made their fortunes
merely by speculation in stocks and shares, but in land speculation;
for land speculation has been bound up from the beginning with the
extension of railways in America. Still, how far, admitting all this,
can Mr. George's statement be considered true?
Now I come to the difficult part of my lecture, and I ask you to be
patient. If you are really eager about these questions, and recognise
as you all must, how huge they are, how they have bewildered men from
the beginning of time, you will be patient; if I tried to make the
problem really simpler than it is, you might justly complain of me. I
could do so, but I should have to use for that purpose illegitimate
artifice.
Let me remind you, the theory is, that [unreadable] the increase of
wealth. How does Mr. George prove this? Let us try and work out his
theory; let us watch how the theory is explained in the development of
a little miniature State. I will try to make the picture as vivid in
your minds as possible. Suppose, for example, one of those settlements
of our Puritan forefathers on the Atlantic coast, and with no commerce
with the outside world. Mr. George says, in the first place, when
these settlers land there is no rent -- anyone can go upon the land,
anywhere. After a time, wealth increases and population increases;
slowly the people move outwards from the settlement, and new pieces of
land are taken into use. Now we must suppose that already the division
between employers and workmen in the industrial system has taken
place, and we have got to ask (and this is the whole point; I am not
going to deal with interest to-night, I am going to deal with wages)
-- what will determine wages in this little settlement? Mr. George
says that wages will be determined by what the labourer can get
working for himself on the land last taken into use. Put it in this
way: supposing the man who works on a piece of land a mile away from
the little group of houses on the sea-coast can get three pecks of
wheat a day as his wage. If an employer in the town says to him, "I
will give you two pecks, if you will work for me at such-and-such a
business," the labourer will say, "No; I will take at least
three, because I can make at least three by working for myself on the
land outside." Therefore, says Mr. George, in a new settlement
wages will be determined by what a man can make working for himself on
the last piece of land taken into use.
Now, how, according to this theory, are we to explain the fall in
wages which takes place? "Oh," says Mr. George, "that
is very simple. As years go on, the whole of that little plain is
occupied, and men begin to carry their cultivation up the sides of the
mountains. Then it is found that the labourer can only earn one peck,
we will say, a day working on the piece of land last taken into use,
and then all through the settlement wages will fall to one peck a day
instead of three; and" the landowner -- we are not now talking of
the capitalist or the employer, we are talking of the landowner --
will sweep off the whole of the increased wealth." That is the
explanation, according to this statement, of the fall of wages with
the advance of civilisation.
Now, in the first place, I wish to point out that this theory assumes
the law of diminishing return -- that is, it assumes that after a time
the return to men's labour will diminish. But that contradicts Mr.
George's statement (with which I entirely agree), that the true law of
agriculture and of industry is a law of increasing return. Mr. George,
however, has an answer, which is obvious on the surface of the book.
He says, "Oh, I don't talk merely of wages as a quantity; I talk
of wages as a proportion." This is Mr. George's answer, in the
first place ; but my reply to Mr. George is this: "If you speak
of wages only as a proportion, how does your theory explain the fall
of wages, the appearance of tramps, and the appearance of poverty m a
new State?" because, though wages might increase or might remain
stationary, yet still, as long as they did not decline, we should be
at a loss to explain by Mr. George's theory the fact which Mr. George
sets out to explain -- the appearance of tramps and the fall of wages
in a new Slate. And, in the next place, if we look carefully at Mr.
George's book itself, we find that all the evidence he gives is of the
fall of wages as a quantity. He tells us that wages in California fell
from 16 dollars a day, say, in 1849, to 20 dollars a day in 1879; so
that the facts which he himself adduces, which he sets out to explain,
are not explained by his theory. Mr. George, however, has yet another
answer to make:
"What I mean," he says, "is, that
speculation in land is the true cause of a fall in wages in a new
State."
To illustrate his contention I will ask you to come back with me to
our little settlement at the sea-side. Mr. George supposes that men
hold on to great tracts of land in that little settlement, and will
not sell it or let it, so that the labourers who want to settle on the
land have to pass this tract, and passing it, are forced by this
artificial cause of land speculation to take poorer land into use.
That being the case, their increased skill, their increased
agricultural knowledge, will not now, owing to pushing back, as it
were, on what Mr. George calls the land line, owing to the pushing
back of cultivation up to the hills, counterbalance the diminishing
fertility of soil in agriculture.
But my answer is again (I am coming to the end of this very soon):
first, Mr. George, you are not consistent with yourself. In various
passages you say that private property in land is the primary,
speculation only a derivative, cause; so that, even if there were not
speculation, wages would fall as a quantity with the advance of
civilisation. But next I ask. Is there any evidence that cultivation
has been pushed in America so far back as to diminish the return to
labour and agriculture? Certainly not. If we may take the price of
wheat as an index, we find that the price between 1810 and 1820
averaged about eight dollars, measured in gold, for a barrel of wheat
in Philadelphia. In 1820 it was nine dollars; but then in 1869 it was
six dollars, measured in gold, and it has been falling, as we know,
since, so that Mr. George brings no evidence as to the diminishing
fertility, as to the diminishing power of labour in agriculture, owing
to the pushing back of the margin of cultivation. Notice, too, that
Mr. George has, curiously enough, neglected altogether -- I suppose it
is to obtain that simplicity which we economists stand so much in need
of in studying things - the mechanism of exchange. For according to
Ricardo's theory, which Mr. George accepts implicitly, the margin of
cultivation, of which we have spoken, instead of determining the wages
and the remuneration of the employed, is itself determined by the
growth of population and wealth and commerce. Let us go back for the
last time to our settlement, and I will show you what is the process
according to Ricardo.
As population advances, poorer lands may be taken into use; but
Ricardo points out that a farmer (he was thinking, of course, of the
English farmer of his own day, who was ploughing up the edges of the
moors and the sheep-walks), though he might get only six bushels per
acre on that new bit of land which is ploughed up on the side of the
hill, would yet expect the same interest and the same wages for
superintendence, and expect to pay his labourers the same wages as
before. In other words, what would happen is, not that he would obtain
a lower remuneration, a smaller share of the general produce of
industry, because he was working on inferior land, but that he would
sell his smaller produce at a higher price. My point is, that wages
and profits -- or we will throw away the word profits, which is a
troublesome one, and say wages and the earnings of the great employers
(for Mr. George, in the most extraordinary way, includes under the
title wages the wages of superintendence, the earnings of these great
employers and iron- masters, and the great grain speculators), the
wages of these men are determined, as a general rule, independently of
the productiveness of the soil, and therefore rent cannot be the cause
of wages and profits falling lower than before. That is Ricardo's
theory of rent, which Mr. George only half understands, and which, as
far as California or any new country is concerned, is true, though
there are exceptions with regard to old countries. Rent, I may as well
admit at once (and I shall deal with this with care in my next
lecture), rent in Ireland and rent in this great City of London; and
rent, again, in some parts of agricultural England, has in certain
cases lowered wages -- that I admit; but then that is owing to a
different cause, which I shall try to explain in my second lecture.
I have now shown, first, that Mr. George's theory is
self-contradictory ; secondly, that he cannot explain by his theory
the facts which he himself adduces; and in the third place, that the
theory is false; not the theory that there is a law of increasing
return, but the theory that it is rent which alone swallows up the
increase. Last of all, in criticising Mr. George, let us ask whether
Mr. George's facts are right; in the first place, whether there is or
is not a fall of wages in California; in the second place, whether
there is or is not a fall of wages in America and our colonies
generally, a matter, mind, of primary importance to workmen who have
to emigrate.
What is the truth about California? Mr. George is quite right in
saying that wages rose from 8s 4d a-day (wages of a common labourer),
to about 3 6s. 8d. a-day in 1849, when the gold discoveries were made.
They fell, however, rapidly ; they were only 12s. 6d. a-day in 1856.
In i860, they fell to 8s. 2d (I am talking of the average wages), but
in 1879, the year in which Mr. George published his book, wages were
higher than they were in i860. They were 9s. a-day, that is the
average wage calculated from statistics supplied by Mr. Tooke in his
History of Prices; by Dr. Young in his Labour in Europe and America
(these are my authorities for wages in California); and, finally, by
Mr. George himself. But if money wages have somewhat increased, the
increase in real wages, i.e., in the amount of the conveniences and
necessaries of life that a workman can obtain with his money, is
greater still, inasmuch as the prices of nearly all the principal
articles of life have fallen about one-third -- were falling about
one-third in California generally between 1856 and 1879.
I am, indeed, not quite satisfied about these facts, although I have
taken immense pains with them. Statistics, I have found, are very
unreliable. One man will tell you about prices of things in San
Francisco, and another man will tell you about the prices of things in
California, and these facts must be taken subject to that
consideration. But what about wages generally in America? That is the
main point. Have they risen, or have they fallen? My own impression
was that they had risen -- real wages I mean -- and I consulted three
American economists: First, Mr. Amasa Walker, a Free-trade economist;
next, Mr. Francis Bowen, a Protectionist economist: and lastly, Mr.
Francis Walker, a Free-trade economist again; and I find that all
these three economists agree that wages -- real wages -- have, on the
whole, risen since 1800. Mr. Francis Walker was the latest writer --
he brings his figures down to 1877; Mr. Amasa Walker down to 1869, and
Mr. Francis Bowen down to 1S70.
So far, then, the figures of the American economists are in favour of
my view; but I was not satisfied with that. I determined to study the
course of wages in our own colonies; and what do I find to be the
case? This: that in the gold colonies, Victoria and New South Wales,
exactly the same line of movement has taken place. Wages were low
before the gold discoveries; they rose rapidly when the gold diggings
were discovered. They have fallen, and have fluctuated, especially the
wages of skilled artisans, a good deal since; but at the present time,
in New South Wales, according to statistics supplied by the
Government, they are higher than they were in 1856; and the New South
Wales correspondent of the Times, writing from Sydney on August 2
last, said also that wages had never been so high as they were at the
present time. You can now justly turn to me, and say: "If that is
so what is your theory of wages? If rent has not reduced wages in
America, if wages have risen, and also along with wages, not interest,
which is a different thing, but the remuneration of management -- the
great gains of speculation -- what is the explanation?" his
explanation is a very simple one. The net produce of American
agriculture and American industry has, as Mr. George has said,
increased during this time, and, as a consequence, the net produce to
be divided between the labourer and the employer and the owner of
capital, of course, is greater than before.
It has thus been possible for the employers and owners of capital to
amass enormous wealth without depriving the labourer of all share in
the increased returns. Mind, I admit that his share is not what it
ought to be. I am only hinting to you that we shall have to look for
our explanation in America, and perhaps in England, to the division of
the net produce between the employer and the workman; but I have not
dealt adequately and fairly with Mr. George until I have shown how his
theory originated. His theory is not a mere fiction of his brain; it
is one that has a natural origin in American experience. His theory,
for example, that wages are determined by what a man can get on the
last land taken into cultivation is by no means an abstract one. If
you study the history of California and of Victoria and of New South
Wales, you will find that all writers -- not only newspaper writers,
but economists -- say that at one time wages in every trade were
determined by what men could get by working at the gold diggings. For
instance, Mr. Tooke, the historian of prices, tells us that men
working at the gold-diggings in Victoria could get about [unreadable]
a week in 1851, and the wages, therefore, in Melbourne were about
[unreadable] a week for all kinds of labour -- the difference being,
of course, accounted for by the risk of the gold trade. The
explanation is, that where there is an unlimited demand for labour in
any one trade, to which labour has ready access, then the wages
obtained in that trade will determine the wages paid in every other
trade. No man will take less -- that is, as a blacksmith or as a
carpenter -- in Melbourne than he can obtain, roughly speaking, at the
gold diggings further oft". It is the same in California. But I
have not done; it is not merely in California that you will find these
facts brought forward and these phrases used. Take the great American
ironmaster, Mr. Hewitt, who was examined before the Trades Union
Commission, and ask him what determines wages in the Eastern States,
and he will say at once, "Oh, what a labourer can get off the
land; that determines wages." He puts it in this way -- "We
great ironmasters in the Eastern States, in Pennsylvania, are obliged
to pay our puddlers at least what they can obtain on the farms in the
West."
There was at the time the words were used a demand, perfectly
unlimited, for labour in agriculture in the West, and therefore any
labourer in an iron foundry in Pennsylvania would say to his master, "Give
me this wage, or I shall go West and take up land, where I can get
that much for myself" On the other hand, of course, wages are
always somewhat lower in an Eastern State, because men prefer to live
in cities; they like the excitement of city life, and they dislike the
solitude and hard life of the West. Then there is one more point
before we have done with this part of our subject. Mr. George says it
was not merely the exhaustion of the rich gold deposits in California
that produced a fall of wages. He maintains, of course, that workmen
got high wages, because anyone could go with his rocker and his spade
to a stream, and simply dig out the gold, wash it in his pan, and sell
the gold dust just as it was there to the dealer. That is, it only
required a pick and a shovel, and a man had nothing more to do than to
dig out the gold. Sometimes these deposits would not yield much gold,
and then, as the result, the labourers got lower wages; that is clear.
But then says Mr. George, "Notice, if you please, that these gold
diggings were common property; no man might hold a claim over one of
them for a longer time than it was in use. He could peg out his claim,
and if he did not use it any one day, then he had to go."
Mr. George is perfectly right. That was the law not only in
California, but in Victoria. Then he says, the Comstock lode was rich
in certain places, and yet the opening of that great vein did not
raise wages. I agree with Mr. George, that had land been monopolised
in California in the first instance, instead of wages rising
everywhere with the gold discoveries, all that the workmen would have
asked would have been a slightly higher wage than they could obtain in
the carpenters shops and the blacksmiths' shops in San Francisco, and
the rest would have gone to the capitalist, in the first instance, who
took the lease, and ultimately to the landlord; it would have gone to
rent. But let me point out, if you please, that Mr. George's own
remedy would not allow wages to rise, because Mr. George proposes to
tax land up to its full value, and, therefore, these gold miners at
the placer deposits would not have had higher wages, but would have
had to yield a large part of the gold which they had obtained to the
State, so that their individual wages would not have risen, though the
gold would have gone to the community, instead of to the individual.
For the rest, I perfectly agree with Mr. George that private property
in land is not essential to good agriculture; that security of tenure
is sufficient; and that it has been an iniquitous mistake on the part
of our own Colonial Governments, and on the part of the Government of
America, to sell land to individuals instead of keeping it for the use
of the people. But this view is not, of course, a new one, it is an
old question in all the colonies.
As long ago as 1856, Mr. Tooke, whom I have quoted so often, an
eminent merchant, who wrote a most valuable "History of Prices,"
proposed that land should be let on lease instead of being sold. And
then, again, it was proposed in Victoria in 1870 and 1873, in the land
agitation of which I have spoken; and as I have said, the principle is
a just one; but there are practical difficulties. I find, for example,
that Mr. Charles Pearson, who has studied the land question from the
extreme radical point of view in Victoria for some time, and has tried
all sorts of methods to prevent land accumulating in the hands of a
few great owners, remarked of this proposal, which he admitted was in
the abstract a just one, that where there was a great number of lease-
holders it would be an extremely dangerous one, because all those
leaseholders would have votes, and could vote about the renewal of
their leases. Well, I do not attribute myself very much importance to
the objection, because not one form alone, but all forms of taxation,
and all forms of exacting wealth from individuals in a new State may
be openings for corruption. But I want to point out that the question
is not such a simple one; and we have seen that earnest and thoughtful
radical land reformers, like Mr. Pearson, do not think it is a very
easy one. The gain to the State, I admit, would be enormous; but
remember that my point is still, that though this revenue would go
into the pockets of the State -- into the Treasury, instead of into
the pockets of individuals -- yet it would not benefit wages, wages
have not, as a general rule, been reduced by the rise of rent, and
they could not be >increased by its confiscation.
I have, last of all, in this explanation, to show you what is the
true theory of the facts -- the true facts which Mr. George adduces. I
have said already that the rapid fall of wages in California and
Victoria was due to the exhaustion of the placer deposits. I admit
that the previous rapid rise was due to the fact that these deposits
were not monopolised by individuals. But now -- this is a very vital
question -- What about the tramps of whom Mr. George speaks? The facts
are astounding. In one pamphlet Mr. George says that the common
estimate in 1878 was that there were 20,000 labourers unemployed in
San Francisco. Another estimate made in 1875 put the number at 10,000.
Now, what is the explanation of the appearance of these tramps, these
vagrants, in a new State -- a most appalling fact? I am not speaking
of Chinamen; they are distinct altogether from European labourers. The
Chinamen numbered about 8,000 in 1870; the figure I have given is the
number of unemployed labourers of European race. At the time of which
I speak there were not only tramps in California, but tramps in Lake
City, and tramps in the new North-West. Why is that? The explanation
is given by Mr. George himself in a pamphlet he wrote on the labour
struggle, and it is to be found in all the recent valuable reports
presented to the Duke of Richmond's Commission en American
agriculture.
It is this -- that with the large farm system of cultivation workmen
cannot obtain regular employment. For instance, take one great farm in
Dakota, which had an area equal to about three times the size of the
City of New York. On this farm in the spring 150 men were employed,
and in the summer 250, and in the winter only 10. What became of these
men? They went to the towns. For, you may say, nine months in the year
the labourers in the great wheat farms in California, the largest
wheat farms in the world, have no employment, and are driven into San
Francisco; and these are the men who, justly perhaps, protest against
Chinese labour, and who meet on the sand-locks in San Francisco, and
propose to remedy their grievances. That is the explanation of tramps
in California and Minnesota and Dakota. I must remind you that Mr.
George does not propose to touch the large farm system. He says the
large farm system is due to a law of economic development, with which
he will not meddle. But as long as vast accumulators of capital
continue to deal thus ruthlessly with their human instruments, what
good will the confiscation of rent do? The evil in this case plainly
is not the ownership of land in large quantities, which is all that
Mr. George would prevent, but its tenure in large quantities, which he
would allow.
What, then, is to be said about this large farm system Is it to go
on? If we look at it closely, we shall find that this is but one
typical form of a universal and urgent problem. It is not only in
farms and in agriculture that great businesses are being formed, or
have been formed, but in industry and manufactures, as we well know
here.
As Karl Marx and other writers have pointed out, gradually large
industries are stamping out, or rather, large businesses are stamping
out, small ones. Gradually capital is being accumulated in fewer and
fewer hands, until at last some think we shall have nothing but a
handful of stupendous monopolists, with a struggling mass of labourers
at their feet. This, I say, is one great cause affecting the division
of produce; it is one great reason why wages have not risen in
proportion to the increase in productive power; it is because the
economic structure of society is such that the huge employer and the
huge capitalist can practically dictate terms to the labourers. What
is the remedy for this? Mr. George offers none. There is one which he
hints at, but I do not think it a serious one. If anyone likes to ask
me afterwards my opinion I will discuss it. Why does Mr. George
propose no remedy? Why does he refuse to meddle with it? Because he is
a believer in what the economists no longer believe in -- in what are
called the "economic harmonies"; that is, he believes, as
Adam Smith believed, and as Bastiat believed, that if you once abolish
private property, or, rather, confiscate the unearned increment, then
individual interests will harmonise with common interests, and
competition, which we know is often now a baneful and destructive
force, will then become a beneficent one.
Now, in justice to Mr. George, again, I must point out that he
proposes that when industries become monopolies they should be
undertaken by the State. Well, I admit that that is the true
principle. They should be either undertaken by the State, or regulated
by the State. We are going to deal, for example, with the Water
Companies in London; and all great industries like the supply of water
and the supply of gas, and so on, which involve necessarily a
monopoly, ought either to be undertaken by the State, or regulated by
the State. But apart from absolute monopoly, there may be the immense
force of great capitalists not in open combination, who are able to
press down wages. What is to be done? I said just now that we
economists abandoned the belief in economic harmonies. What do we,
then, think of the economic self-interest which most socialists
denounce as a thing to be destroyed? We say that economic
self-interest more resembles a great physical force than anything
else, the laws of which must be studied in order that it may be
controlled. For example, take self-interest working in the great grain
market. To buy in the cheapest and sell in the dearest market is to
take a thing from where it is least wanted to where it is most wanted.
Here is a service, therefore, rendered by self-interest to the
community; not that the great grain speculators are not over-paid ;
still self-interest does work, where they have not a monopoly, for the
good of the community as a whole. But look at self-interest working in
the destruction of life in mines and factories.
We know very well what this was; we know very well there were no
economic harmonies there. The absence of economic harmonies is to be
read in that terrible history of the degradation of men, and women,
and children which is to be found in our own Government reports. But
while we regard competition as resembling a physical force, in that it
admits of and demands study and control, we do not allow that it is,
like physical forces, unalterable in itself. Whilst you cannot change
the elements of nature, but only learn their secret and control them,
human nature can change. Man we recognise now is not like a rock or a
stone, but is pliable, and pliable to great ideas of justice. We need
no longer crouch and shiver under the shadow of inexorable law. Man is
master of his fate. Still I know there are some who will say this is
an idle dream. Men always have followed their self-interest without
remorse; men always will follow their self-interest without remorse. I
deny that. But I admit that we cannot wait for the time when higher
ideals will control men's self-interest, and that the economists, it
they admit that the economic harmonies are to a large extent a
fiction, are bound to admit the necessity for more administration and
control. That is true. The era of free trade and free contract is
gone, and the era of administration has come.
Not only has the era come, but silently it has been upon us before we
knew it. Throughout the whole of this century, when we were busy
unshackling our trade and flinging open our ports to the whole world,
we were at the same time - against, I admit, the protests of the
economists -- hemming in the disastrous and virulent greed of
employers, passing Factory Acts, prohibiting the labour of women in
mines, protecting women and children everywhere. But in 1881 we began
a new era, for in that year an Act was passed which extended the
protection of the State, which is the organised power of the community
for good, not merely to women and children, but to men -- I mean the
Irish Land Act. The author of that remarkable phrase in 1864, the man
who said that for the great majority of beings life was a bare
struggle for existence, unconsciously redeemed his utterance. He
unconsciously redeemed his pledge, and by passing the Irish Land Act -
though he may deny it, and it may be necessary for him to deny it,
there is no reason why we should -- he has committed the Radical party
to a socialist programme.
What I mean by socialism is this. I do not mean the destruction of
private property; I do not mean communism; but I do mean the extension
of the protection of the State not only to women and children, but, if
need be, to men, because men also -- agricultural labourers and
workers in mines and factories -- are but too often not free agents.
Here, however, arises a great problem. We shall have to carry out
these measures without undermining that old independence, that habit
of voluntary association, of which we are justly proud, for if we
undermine that -- that pride which has made the English workman
sacrifice everything to keep himself out of the workhouse, which has
made workmen bind themselves together in Friendly Societies and Trades
Unions and in Co-operative Societies -- if we undermine that, then it
would be better to leave our work undone. But I believe it can be
done. I believe that the problems of administration, difficult as they
are, can be solved if men will only have patience, and in my next
lecture I hope to sketch in outline a programme of administration,
dealing with wages, the dwellings of the poor, the question of
insurance, and the question of the recreations of the people. All
these things I hope to deal with, and will try to show that without
revolution and without socialism, in the continental sense, we shall
be able to do something towards that better distribution of wealth
which we all desire to see. But if we undertake a more complicated
work of administration, remember, in the first place, that we are
dealing, again, not with physical facts, but with the compound of
sensibilities and interests shaped by ages of history and change which
we call man, and that the thing is not simple -- it is difficult; that
it will require not only the thought of one man, but the thought of
many, and not only the thought of many, but the patience of more; and
if, again, administration is to be successful, it means one thing
more: it means devotion to the community.
\For all these new proposals will only open up new opportunities for
corruption, unless at the same time we raise ourselves to the
occasion, and determine that we will, in proposing them and in working
them out, be actuated with no other feeling than a passionate devotion
to the community. "But, alas!" many of you will say, "such
a thing needs faith, and our faith is in ruins," I answer, "True,
your faith is in ruins ; but I think also that in spite of darkness
and bewilderment and tears, there will come a purer faith, a faith
which, cleared of superstitious control, shall make devotion to the
community no longer a troubled and uncertain refuge from doubt, but a
source of a pure and tranquil inner life." But we need not wait
for that, and if men individually will but make up their minds to do
all that in them lies to bring about the great event for which the
people have longed for so many centuries, the thing will be done --
the reign of social justice will have come.
|