.


SCI LIBRARY

Libertarian Land Philosophy:
Man's Eternal Dilemma

Oscar B. Johannsen, Ph.D.



BOOK II: Exchange and Money

Chapter 3 - Credit-Time-Barter



Because man has memory, he has been able to evolve a form of barter which expanded exchange to a degree almost unimaginable. This is known as credit.

As has been pointed out before, credit is the exchange of goods in the present upon the promise of the receipt of other goods at some future time. More exactly. it is the voluntary surrender of the rights to goods in the present upon the promise of the rights to other goods to be received at some future time. Credit is time-barter, that is. it is barter over a period of time.

Credit may have arisen simultaneously with the evolution of ordinary barter, although it probably preceded it. A native, desperate with hunger, may have begged his neighbor for food promising to give some game in return the next time he caught some. Such an act may have given to man the idea of exchanging goods.

History teaches that credit probably arose through the borrowing of seeds. At the end of the harvest period, the borrower was expected to return some other seeds from the crop together with some of the produce, Some of the earliest records of the Seventeenth Century indicate that in America occasionally credit was extended to the Indians. When their crop of corn was low, they obtained corn on credit from the colonists, especially from the Dutch in New York and from the English in Massachusetts. In return, the next year they would give their creditors other goods such as beaver skins.

The colonists extended credit to one another in the form of food, seed, powder or shot in return for an agreed-upon portion of the following year's crop. On the frontier, where the settlers were all faced with the serious problems of food and protection, it was considered almost a duty to grant credit to a frontiersman and questions as to financial responsibility were not raised.

Merchants have always granted credit. For example, shortly before the Civil War many wholesale dry-goods merchants extended credit to western and southern retail merchants. The retailer would be sent the dry-goods he desired upon his promise to pay for them, usually within a year in money and in other goods. The retailer often would pledge not to seek credit from anyone else until his indebtedness was discharged. This credit was granted by the wholesaler based on his knowledge of the buyer and his judgment of the retailer's ability and character.

The retailer, in turn, would often grant credit to his customers. A prominent 18th century merchant, Edgward D. Page, stated that in rural areas "the country bank was almost unknown: its functions, so far as they were the needs of a rural or semi-rural community, were performed in large measure, by the retail merchant himself, who traded upon an elaborate system of accounts receivable and payable, which needed very little cash. My father, who graduated from one of these country stores, has often told me that they frequently went through a week's business without so much as five dollars in real money."[1]

Today, a huge volume of credit is granted by commercial outfits directly to their customers. This is carried on the books as accounts or notes receivable. Payment may be in 30, 60, 90, or 120 days.

Credit initially was granted on verbal promises, such as occurred on the frontier. However, as commerce grew, verbal promises had to give way to written promises. It was not only that memories are short but communications between merchants usually were written because of the distances and the quantities of goods involved. A retailer would give a wholesaler a note promising to pay for the goods purchased. Many of such notes were three, five or ten days after sight, which means after presentation of the note for payment. They were written in terms of money. In the colonies, because the money in use varied so much, consisting of Spanish, Portuguese and English coins, as well as coins of other countries, the notes usually designated the specific currency desired.

Instead of being immediately presented for payment, these notes, or domestic bills of exchange, as they were called, often were endorsed and passed from merchant to merchant in payment of debts until finally presented for redemption. In like fashion, a promissory note of a wealthy man would often pass from hand to hand for several months, helping to make exchanges of goods much as money did. (The nature of this process will be explained in the chapter on money-aids.)

The length of time for which credit was usually granted in colonial times is not too well known, possibly because there were no customary terms. Probably the time involved was for one, three, nine or twelve months although some records indicate that some merchants granted credit on active accounts for as long as five years. Most of the early credit dealings were pure barter transactions over time with no money involved and were known as 'trusting' transactions. They were based on friendship and neighborliness.

By the 18th Century, importer-wholesalers usually granted credit for about twelve months to their retail customers, shopkeepers and country general stores. "In 1737, Peter Faneuil, the active young merchant who built and gave Faneuil Hall to Boston, wrote to M. Miguel Pacheco da Silva, London, that he had sold imported goods at '12 & 15 Months Credit & if I can get paid for them in two Years time I shall account myself well of." [2]

Storekeepers needing credit were quite willing to buy merchandise at higher prices than the cash prices. People, today, who buy on the installment plan pay as much as one-third more than for cash. As is true today, wholesale and retail merchants in earlier days were forced by competition to accommodate their customers with credit or else they would lose business.

Initially credit involved only ordinary goods. However, when money arose it was perfectly natural that it would become part of the credit system. 'Country pay' was perfectly acceptable in early American life, when conditions were relatively primitive. This was payment in terms of goods produced in rural areas, as corn and home-made articles. But. as money became increasingly available, debts were incurred in money, or at least in terms of money. Today, most credit dealings involve money. The debtor receives goods upon promising to pay money to the creditor at a later date, as when one purchases a radio or television set on time. Now, of course, credit involves not only the borrowing of goods to be paid for subsequently in money, but the borrowing of money, itself.

Two factors of prime importance are involved in credit. The first is trust; the second is time.

No credit will be extended if there is no trust. The creditor ponders the likelihood that the borrower will live up to his promise. Is he trustworthy? Will he live up to his obligations even it he sustains a loss by so doing? Is he likely to live long enough to fulfill the contract? Does he have the capability of completing the transaction? Many questions will rise in the mind of the creditor, all of which add up to a question of trust.

If the creditor trusts the borrower, then the question of time enters. For how long should he extend credit? If the time desired is too long, then, no matter how much he may trust the other party, he will not extend credit. Few men will grant credit for more than forty or fifty years. Loans ordinarily do not run for longer than a generation. Most are for relatively short periods, probably less than five years, with the greater proportion for less than a year.

The time element is not only the concern of the creditor but of the borrower. He wants to borrow food today for he needs it in order to live. A retailer needs goods today, or he will lose many sales.

That credit is time-barter may appear peculiar to the reader for it is not ordinarily viewed in that light. However, the credit arrangements in colonial America may help convince the reader that such is the case.

The famed country storekeeper would barter with his customers over a period of time. The grain, butter, cheese, eggs and household manufactures, as yarn and hand-made nails, which were produced in his area would be turned over to him. He would give credit to the sellers toward future purchases of city goods. When the goods arrived, the customers would take the articles desired to the extent of the credit which they had built up. In other words, a farmer would barter his present goods --- his farm and household products -- for future goods -- the city goods. This was barter over time.

The storekeeper, in turn, bartered with city wholesalers over time. Usually, the wholesaler extended the credit to the storekeeper. He would ship combs, knives, imported dress goods, handkerchiefs, paper, cloth, crockery, glassware, sugar and salt. These were paid for over periods of six, nine or twelve months with grain, cheese, eggs and household goods. i.e., 'country goods'.

Such transactions were clearly barter arrangements. However, a money terminology was used and the goods credited or debited were in terms of money. The storekeeper would credit a farmer for his 'country goods' at prices agreed upon between them, Similarly, his dealings with the city wholesalers were in terms of money.

Barter was carried on in city areas as late as the latter part of the l8th century. In 1768, an advertisement indicated that such trade was carried on quite extensively in a center as large as New York City. A store offered rum, molasses, tea, pepper and other articles in return for most kinds of country produce.[3]

The reader nay be a bit puzzled why so much emphasis is placed on the fact that credit is the exchange of present goods for future goods. It is because as credit evolves into complex forms, and particularly with the intrusion of governments in monetary matters, people tend to lose sight of what credit really is. If the reader will mentally substitute 'time-barter' whenever the word credit appears, he will most likely have a better understanding of what is occurring.

It should be obvious by now that credit, as defined in this book, means that banks, which are assumed to be the greatest grantors of credit, actually are not. Since credit is the exchange of present goods for future goods, it is clear that the true grantors of credit are the producers of goods. To the extent that banks extend credit in the form of actual money, they give credit, but this is a relatively small amount.

This does not mean that banks do not play a tremendously important part in credit transactions, for they do. Highly complex machinery has been evolved to assist in the extension of credit, and banks are in the forefront in rendering such aid. But this function is not so much the granting of credit by banks, as it is the guaranteeing of trust. As the first and most important element in credit is trust, obviously if some means can be devised by man which will reduce the problem of trust to minor proportions, then credit transactions will be aided immensely. Banks perform this function, as will be shown subsequently.

To make credit a bit clearer, it might be wise to review the fundamentals more explicitly. Bearing in mind that credit is the exchange of the rights to present goods for the rights to future goods, the following is an hypothesis of how it probably evolved.

First an individual would ask another to extend credit in the form of some good, such as food, in return for his promise to return another good in the future.

Next, credit took the form of exchanging a good in the present upon the promise of receiving a particular good in the future, that good being money. Today, it is known as installment credit. People purchase appliances in the present and promise to pay for them in the future in installments.

The third step would be the extension of credit in the form of money being lent in the present upon the promise of receiving other money in the future. These are classified as loans of money.

Although initially credit was carried on a verbal basis, it probably was not long before evidence of the credit granted involved some form of written proof. It could be that upon receiving an apple, a man might have written a note to the effect that he would give his friend an orange the next day. It is not likely that this would actually happen in such a simple transaction but when credit was extended in the form of large quantities of goods and for money, verbal promises would certainly be supplanted by written ones. They would start out by being simple IOU's such as 'I owe John Angle Three dollars'. This IOU might ultimately be extended to include time and place of payment and might include other provisions. Today, we have sophisticated IOU's, such as the demand deposits of commercial banks. No matter how complex IOU's may be today, they are nothing but aids to enable the actual producers of goods to extend credit to other people. Most people are probably unaware of this. They believe that IOU's, or credit instruments as they are usually called, such as bills of exchange, bankers' acceptances, banknotes and demand deposits are some of the mysterious devices by which banks directly or indirectly create money. But all of them are merely IOU's no different in principle from the very first one written by some primitive merchant.

Parenthetically, it might not be amiss to point out that there is a subtle distinction between a credit transaction and a loan. Since credit is barter over time, it means that an orange today is being bartered for an apple tomorrow. On the other hand, a loan implies that the identical article of wealth loaned will be subsequently returned. If a friend lends you a book, he may be quite annoyed if later you return a copy of it rather than the identical one as you had lost his. In lending money, the identical coins may not be expected in return, but it amounts to the same thing as people are indifferent as long as the returned money is of the same quality and amount.

The contrast between a credit and a loan transaction may be a distinction without a difference for they tend to be considered alike. One difference which may have some significance is that a loan tends to come out of savings. A credit transaction, on the other hand, is more likely to be the result of ordinary business dealings.

In the case of credit, banks are guaranteeing that the buyers will deliver the money for the goods purchased. In the case of loans, banks should lend actual money, that is wealth. Instead, they ordinarily give the borrowers banknotes or, credit them with demand deposits, that is, the banks give their guarantees. But guarantees, while they may be important are not substantial. They are not something material. Conservative economists have always insisted that commercial banks should lend funds on capital or real estate only to the extent that the banks have received deposits of what are termed savings, i.e., time or savings deposits. By so doing, these economists are actually making a distinction between credit and loans. They are making a distinction between a bank putting up its guarantee and a bank putting up actual wealth -- money. (It is true that this distinction is not clear cut inasmuch as money is considered to be the banknotes of a nation's central bank as well as gold or silver. Nonetheless, the distinction is there.)

When a nation tinkers with its money and thereby loses the confidence of the peoples of the world so that no one will accept its money, the people in that country are still able to make exchanges among themselves and with foreigners. It is done quite clumsily, but it is still accomplished. As between nations, it is done through barter arrangements. The nation with worthless money usually establishes some agency with a fancy title, as Exchange Stabilization Bureau, which makes deals with other nations. The goods exchanged may be at ratios determined by the prices of the nation with the sound money or of a third nation. This is inefficient, but it works.

It were not for the fact that fundamentally all exchanges are barter exchanges, the interference of the State in monetary matters would make exchanges impossible. It is somewhat analogous to water flowing down a hill. Despite all the obstacles which man may erect, the water still finds it way to the bottom. Similarly, despite all the interferences in monetary matters by the State, exchanges will go on although at much greater cost to the people than if the State had not interfered.


Recapitulation


Credit is time-barter. It is the bartering of goods over a period of time. More exactly, it is the bartering of the rights to goods over a period of time, With the advent of money, it became largely the bartering of goods in the present for money in the future, or the bartering of money in the present for money in the future.

The two principal factors involved in credit are trust and time. Trust is primarily a consideration of the creditor as he considers whether he will extend credit. The time element is a consideration of both parties. Banks are very important in facilitating credit, their principal function being the reduction of the problem of trust, thereby acting as a guarantor of trust.

Preface and Introduction

BOOK 1

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 2

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2 * Chapter 3 * Chapter 4
Chapter 5 * Chapter 6

BOOK 3

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 4

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 5

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 6

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 7

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2 * Chapter 3

BOOK 8

Chapter 1

BOOK 9

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 10

Bibliography